From The Archives Of The American And International Left -The Origins of Japanese Communism, Debate over “Two-Stage Revolution” and the American Occupation
Markin comment:
This archival issue of the Spartacist journal may be of some historical interest for old "new leftists,” perhaps, as well as for younger militants interested in various political, cultural and social questions that intersect and directly affect the ebb and flow of the class struggle. Or for those just interested in a Marxist position on a series of social and political questions that are thrust upon us by the vagaries of bourgeois society. I will be posting more such articles from the back issues ofSpartacist and other periodicals from other leftist organizations, past and present, periodically throughout the year.
Additional Markin comment:
I place some material in this space which may be of interest to the radical public that I do not necessarily agree with or support. Off hand, as I have mentioned before, I think it would be easier, infinitely easier, to fight for the socialist revolution straight up than some of the“remedies” provided by the commentators in these entries. But part of that struggle for the socialist revolution is to sort out the “real” stuff from the fluff as we struggle for that more just world that animates our efforts.
************
************
Spartacist English edition No. 58
|
Spring 2004
|
The Origins of Japanese Communism, Debate over “Two-Stage
Revolution” and the American Occupation
The Meiji Restoration: A Bourgeois Non-Democratic Revolution
Appendix: Historical Documents
This article follows the standard Japanese practice of listing
family names before given names. With the exception of the Japanese Communist
Party, which is always given in English, the names of Japanese institutions and
organizations are rendered in romaji transliterations. The first time a
transliterated name appears, the English translation is given in
parentheses.
Today, Germany and Japan are second only to the United States as
the major capitalist-imperialist powers in the world. In the mid 19th century,
both these countries underwent “revolutions from above” which removed the feudal
(in Japan) and feudal-derived (in Germany) obstacles to their subsequent
development as modern capitalist societies and states. In Germany, Prussian
chancellor Otto von Bismarck waged a series of wars from 1864-71, unifying the
country under the Hohenzollern monarchy and modernizing the state structure.
Bismarck’s actions greatly strengthened an already economically ascendant
industrial, financial and commercial bourgeoisie. In Japan, a section of the old
warrior caste, wielding the image of the Emperor Meiji, ousted the feudal regime
in 1867-68 to build up the Japanese military and enable it to stand up to the
encroachments of the Western powers. In the following decades, they created a
Japanese industrial bourgeoisie. By the beginning of the 20th century, Germany
had become the strongest industrial capitalist state in Europe, Japan the only
industrial capitalist state in Asia.
Both Western and Japanese academics have long recognized the
substantial similarity of the course of development of Germany and Japan.
However, when the Japanese Communist Party (JCP) was founded in 1922, Japan was
much more backward in all major respects—social, economic and political—than
Germany; not only the Germany of the interwar Weimar Republic but also the
pre-1918 Germany of the Hohenzollern monarchy. The emperor ruled not merely “by
the grace of god” but as the descendant of the sun goddess, the mythical founder
of the Japanese nation. Half the Japanese labor force was still engaged in
agriculture, for the most part utilizing pre-industrial technology.
While the leaders of the early Communist International (CI, or
Comintern) sometimes referred to Japan as the “Prussia of the East,” there was
no unanimity on the nature of Japan as an advanced, industrial society
qualitatively similar to Germany. The main CI leader assigned to help the
Japanese party, Nikolai Bukharin, insisted that Japan remained “semi-feudal.”
Beginning in the fall of 1922, the CI sought to impose on the JCP cadre
Bukharin’s analysis of Japan, and with it the two-stage schema of revolution
which the CI was then imposing on all the young Communist parties of the East.
The JCP was instructed to fight for a bourgeois-democratic revolution in which
the Communist Party would join with the liberal bourgeoisie and the peasants in
overthrowing the monarchy; it was only with the completion of the
bourgeois-democratic stage that the Communist Party was to begin the fight for
socialism. Moreover, those in the CI leadership responsible for the JCP failed
to straightforwardly apply the lessons of Bolshevik organization under tsarist
repression—the need for a stable émigré leadership center and network of
couriers to maintain contact with and provide propaganda for underground party
cells in Japan. Thus the JCP was set up to be destroyed by the severe state
repression.
Under the impact of the burgeoning bureaucratic degeneration of the
Soviet state and party, the Communist International in the fall of 1922 was
showing the first signs of abandoning its internationalist purpose (see
“Rearming Bolshevism: A Trotskyist Critique of Germany 1923 and the Comintern,”
Spartacist No. 56, Spring 2001). The isolation of the Soviet Union and
the extreme backwardness of the old tsarist empire—made worse by the destruction
wrought by World War I and the Civil War of 1918-20—led to the development of a
bureaucratic caste within the world’s first workers state. This bureaucracy
usurped political power from the proletariat at the Thirteenth Party Conference
in January 1924 and toward the end of that year Stalin propounded the dogma of
building “socialism in one country,” the theoretical rationale for this
conservative, nationalist layer.
Over the next decade the zigzags and increasing class
collaborationism of the Comintern’s policies, first under Zinoviev and then
under Bukharin and Stalin, led to disaster after disaster as the Communist
parties were gradually transformed into border guards for the Soviet Union and
instruments of its foreign policy. Trotsky fought the CI’s growing misleadership
of revolutionary struggles. Standing on the political heritage of the
Comintern’s first four congresses, he built the Left Opposition in battle
against the CI’s abandonment of a revolutionary perspective, especially in
China. There the program of “two-stage revolution” provided the cover for the
subordination of the interests of the Chinese proletariat to those of Chiang
Kai-shek’s Guomindang (with which the Soviet Union was seeking an alliance
against British imperialism). The result was the strangling of a nascent
proletarian revolution in 1925-27: the “first stage” was the Chinese Communists’
political liquidation into the bourgeois-nationalist forces, the “second stage”
was the physical extermination of the Communists and advanced workers at the
hands of these same bourgeois forces, most notably in the Shanghai massacre of
April 1927.
Forcibly exiled from the Soviet Union in 1929, over the next decade
Trotsky built a movement which resulted in the founding of a new communist
international, the Fourth International, in 1938. The Comintern’s degeneration
culminated in the adoption of an explicit program of class collaboration (the
“popular front”) at the Seventh CI Congress in 1935. In 1943, Stalin dissolved
the Comintern in the interests of his World War II alliance with British,
American and French imperialism.
Trotsky did not write specifically about Japan until the 1930s, and
then only infrequently and mainly in articles about the military situation in
the Pacific leading into WWII. By this time the JCP had been crushed by state
repression. In a 1933 article Trotsky commented that the Meiji Restoration
represented “not a ‘bourgeois revolution,’ as some historians say, but a
bureaucratic attempt to buy off such a revolution” (“Japan Heads for Disaster,”
12 July 1933). However, Trotsky viewed Japan as a full-fledged imperialist
power, standing on a qualitatively higher level of social and economic
development than semicolonies like China. He defended China against Japanese
imperialist invasion in the 1930s. A resolution adopted at the founding
conference of the Fourth International stated with regard to Japan: “Bourgeois
property relations and the capitalist system of exploitation, extending over
both the proletariat and the peasantry, decree revolutionary overthrow of the
ruling class and the establishment of the dictatorship of the proletariat as the
only reed of salvation for both workers and peasants” (“The War in the Far East
and the Revolutionary Perspectives,” September 1938, Documents of the Fourth
International).
Taking off from Trotsky’s 1933 comment about the Meiji Restoration,
the Spartacist Group Japan (SGJ), Japanese section of the International
Communist League, had the position that the Meiji Restoration represented an
“incomplete” bourgeois-democratic revolution. For example, the SGJ wrote that
“The Meiji Restoration was not a bourgeois revolution, but a defensive measure
by the feudal bureaucracy for themselves” (Spartacist [Japan] No. 16, May
1994).
This present article is the result of some extensive research and
discussion within the ICL on the development of Japanese capitalism and the
history of the early JCP, in the course of which the Japanese comrades have come
to change their understanding of the Meiji Restoration and its implications.
However, we recognize that our article is limited because the research is based
mainly on English-language sources, as well as some newly published material
from the Comintern archives (see endnote).
Social Origins of the Meiji Restoration
Japan’s revolution from above in the late 1860s resulted from the
intersection of two deeply rooted historical developments: the slow decay of
Japanese feudalism caused by its own inner contradictions and the violent
intrusion of Western imperialism in East Asia.
The Japanese feudal polity was marked by a curious dualism between
the emperor and the shogun (generalissimo or commander). The emperor was
universally recognized as the supreme authority of the Japanese nation. However,
throughout the history of medieval Japan real power was wielded by the
shogun, a member of one of the most powerful feudal clans. The emperor
remained secluded, often forcibly, in Kyoto, a semi-mystical figure uninvolved
in the actual course of political events.
In 1600, Tokugawa Ieyasu defeated his rivals in the famous battle
of Sekigahara and established the Tokugawa shogunate (or Bakufu), which
ruled Japan for the next two and a half centuries. Through a policy of rigid
national isolationism, Japan preserved its independence during the first phase
of Western imperialist expansion in the era of mercantile capitalism. The
Bakufu also effectively suppressed the warfare among the daimyo
(feudal lords) which had been endemic to medieval Japan. However, the very
successes and stability of the Tokugawa state set in motion social forces which
eventually led to its overthrow.
With an end to the continual warfare, the hereditary warrior caste,
the samurai, lost its traditional role in Japanese society. Barred from
engaging in trade, many samurai became impoverished and deeply alienated
from the existing order. Some became ronin (wandering men), or masterless
samurai, owing fealty to no lord and professing no fixed occupation.
The long Tokugawa peace, the Bakufu’s construction of a
network of roads connecting different parts of the country, and the development
of coastal shipping all facilitated a substantial and steady increase in
agricultural production and handicraft (pre-industrial) manufactures. The main
beneficiary of this economic growth were the shonin (merchants),
especially the big rice dealers of Osaka like the Mitsui family. Many a
daimyo and samurai found themselves deeply in debt to the powerful
merchant families.
However, the further development of mercantile capital in Japan was
blocked by the prohibitions on foreign trade, restrictions on the purchase and
sale of land and the division of the country into hundreds of han (feudal
domains), each with its own border guards and currency. By the first decades of
the 19th century, the frustrated ambitions of the great merchant houses and
their allies in the cities converged with the discontents of nationalistic,
modernizing elements among the samurai. Historians have called this the
union of “the yen with the sword.”
E. Herbert Norman wrote in 1940 a pioneering study on the origins
of modern Japan, Japan’s Emergence as a Modern State (Toronto: UBC Press,
2000 [1940]), which drew heavily on the rich historical scholarship of Japanese
Marxist intellectuals. Norman explained:
“The chonin [townspeople] felt that their own prosperity
was closely tied to that of the warrior and noble classes, their customers and
debtors. For this reason the chonin never dreamed of making a frontal
assault on feudalism as a system, although they were prepared to finance a
political movement against the Bakufu in concert with rival
feudal elements.” (emphasis in original)
The son of Canadian Protestant missionaries, Norman spent his
childhood in rural Japan in the 1910s and ’20s. Under the impact of the rise of
fascism in Germany in the early 1930s, he was attracted to the left and briefly
joined the British Communist Party while a student at Cambridge University. For
this, among other reasons, Norman’s book was buried, particularly by American
academics, during the Cold War. Then a member of the Canadian diplomatic corps,
Norman was hounded to his death by the American McCarthyites, finally committing
suicide in 1957.
According to the traditional feudal hierarchy, the peasants stood
below the samurai, but above artisans and merchants. The growth of trade
and a money economy undermined the traditional structure and stability of the
Japanese village, with a few peasants becoming richer and others falling into
penury. A growing population of urbanized (propertyless) manual laborers came
into being. Early 19th-century Japan saw a rising incidence of peasant revolts
against feudal exactions and also rice riots in the cities directed against
merchant speculators and the government officials who protected them.
The growing social tensions in late feudal Japan were brought to a
critical point, resulting in civil war, by the direct threat of Western military
conquest. In the 1840s, the Japanese ruling classes looked on with shock and
trepidation as Britain defeated and humiliated China in the Opium War, annexed
Hong Kong and reduced the “Celestial Kingdom”—the center of East Asian
civilization since time immemorial—to semicolonial subjugation. In 1853, an
American naval fleet under Commodore Perry forced its way into Tokyo Bay,
demanding trade concessions. Unable to resist militarily, the Tokugawa shogunate
agreed to unequal commercial treaties with the United States and the European
powers and granted Western nationals extraterritorial legal rights in Japan.
These concessions led to an organized opposition to the
Bakufu expressed in the slogan: “Revere the emperor! Expel the
barbarian!” In other words, only a strong central government ruled directly by
the emperor could preserve Japan’s independence. The anti-Bakufu forces were
concentrated in the domains of 86 tozama (“outside” lords), the historic
enemies of the Tokugawa dynasty. These oppositional han now came under
the de facto leadership of modernizing samurai who built up their
military strength along Western lines.
The decade-long maneuvers and struggle for power between the
Bakufu and the tozama—with four clans, Satsuma, Choshu, Tosa and
Hizen, in the leadership—culminated in 1868 in a brief civil war which ended
with the defeat of the Bakufu. Breaking sharply with Japanese feudal
tradition, Choshu enrolled peasants and other commoners into its army. The
victors established a new government in the name of the supreme authority of the
Emperor Meiji. Hence this historical event is called the Meiji Ishin
(Restoration). However, the leaders of the new regime mostly governed
independently of the emperor, who was seen to be above the political battles of
the time.
Over the next few years, this regime introduced a series of
measures amounting to a revolutionary transformation of broad scope: recognition
of the legal equality of all classes, abolition of feudal dress, establishment
of state schools, reform of the calendar, formal emancipation of the forebears
of the Burakumin (considered a pariah caste because they dealt with dead animals
and leather tanning), removal of the feudal ban on alienation and partition of
land, establishment of the freedom to choose one’s occupation, etc. Japan
imported the most modern industry and technology. In the 1870s, more than 2,000
experts—mathematicians, scientists, engineers—were recruited to teach the basic
sciences that made modern industry possible. For training in engineering,
government technical schools were established with foreign instructors, while
the best Japanese students were sent abroad to master the most up-to-date
techniques.
While the forces leading the Meiji Restoration were internal to
Japan, their success was strongly conditioned by favorable international
circumstances. The main rival Western powers were unable or unwilling to
intervene decisively at this critical juncture in Japan’s history. Tsarist
Russia, which had ambitions toward the Kurile Islands on Japan’s northern
fringes, was still recovering from its defeat at the hands of Britain and France
in the Crimean War of the 1850s. The United States was internally preoccupied
with the deep political fissures and profound socio-economic dislocations of its
own momentous Civil War a few years earlier. The interventions of Britain and
France in Japan in a sense cancelled each other out, with the latter supporting
the Bakufu and the former the anti-Tokugawa forces.
More generally, for all of these Western states China was the main
target and great prize in East Asia, with Japan regarded as relatively poor
pickings. As Norman put it, “It was the sprawling prostrate body of China which
acted as a shield for Japan against the mercantile and colonial greed of the
European Powers.” Thus in the historical short run, the Japanese ruling classes
had a wide latitude to radically restructure their state.
Toward a Dialectical Understanding of the Meiji Restoration
How can one characterize the Meiji Restoration as a bourgeois
revolution if it was not led by the bourgeoisie? The bourgeoisie did not
directly lead the French Revolution either—the Jacobins were led by lawyers like
Robespierre and other petty-bourgeois professionals, supported by the urban
artisan masses and land-hungry peasants. However, it was the commercial and
financial bourgeoisie who were in a position to benefit from the overthrow of
the monarchy and the abolition of feudal impediments to national economic
development, laying the basis for a nascent industrial bourgeoisie within two
generations. The lower samurai, who spearheaded the Meiji Restoration,
could legitimately be described as a military-bureaucratic caste or stratum. In
order to survive as a nationally independent ruling class, they had to transform
Japan into a modern industrial capitalist country and therewith foster the
development of an industrial bourgeoisie. Their policies and actions led within
two generations to the development of an industrial/financial bourgeoisie as the
dominant social class in Japan.
Here it is instructive to look at the Bismarckian “revolution from
above” in Germany. In doing so it is also necessary to recognize certain
fundamental differences, as well as important parallelisms, between Germany and
Japan in the late 19th century. Germany stood at a qualitatively higher level of
economic development, with a substantial industry and an already economically
dominant bourgeoisie which, however, confronted a rapidly growing, socially and
politically conscious proletariat.
The extension of the socio-economic achievements of the French
Revolution to western and southern Germany through military conquest under the
Napoleonic empire gave a powerful impetus to the development of industrial as
well as commercial capitalism. On the eve of the Revolution of 1848, Engels
wrote of the German bourgeoisie:
“Although its advance during the last thirty years has not been
nearly as great as that of the English and French bourgeoisie, it has
nevertheless established most branches of modern industry, in a few districts
supplanted peasant or petty-bourgeois patriarchalism, concentrated capital to
some extent, produced something of a proletariat, and built fairly long
stretches of railroad. It has at least reached the point of having either to go
further and make itself the ruling class or to renounce its previous conquests,
the point where it is the only class that can at the moment bring about progress
in Germany, can at the moment rule Germany.”
— “The Constitutional Question in Germany” (June 1847)
However, during the upheaval of 1848 the bourgeoisie’s fear that a
radical democratic revolution would be but a prelude to a “red revolution,”
centrally based on the urban working class, drove it into an alliance with the
forces of monarchical reaction. Marx and Engels concluded that the European
bourgeoisie had already turned reactionary. As a result, Marx ended his address
of the Central Authority to the Communist League in March 1850 with the famous
cry for “The Revolution in Permanence.”
With the further rapid development of industrial capitalism, the
main body of the German bourgeoisie formed an alliance with the Prussian landed
nobility (the Junkers), which laid the basis for Bismarck’s “revolution from
above” in the 1860s. Bismarck began as a political representative of the Junkers
and had been an extreme reactionary in the Revolution of 1848-49. But he
represented this feudal-derived class in the era of industrial capitalism, in
which Prussia confronted more advanced bourgeois states: Britain and France.
Bismarck came to understand that only the industrial/financial bourgeoisie could
transform Germany into a comparably advanced state and thereby ensure the
survival, and indeed prosperity, of the old landed classes as well.
In the late 1880s, Engels wrote in this regard:
“A person in Bismarck’s position and with Bismarck’s past, having
a certain understanding of the state of affairs, could not but realise that the
Junkers, such as they were, were not a viable class, and that of all the
propertied classes only the bourgeoisie could lay claim to a future, and that
therefore (disregarding the working class, an understanding of whose historical
mission we cannot expect of him) his new empire promised to be all the stabler,
the more he succeeded in laying the groundwork for its gradual transition to a
modern bourgeois state.”
—Engels, The Role of Force in History (1887-88)
The Prussian Junkers became large-scale agrarian capitalists and
the Hohenzollern monarchy operated effectively free of parliamentary control.
While the Reichstag (parliament) had some influence over domestic policies, it
had no effective control over foreign affairs and the military. As Engels wrote
in 1891: “The German empire is a monarchy with semi-feudal institutions, but
dominated ultimately by the economic interests of the bourgeoisie” (“Socialism
in Germany”).
Considered dialectically, the Meiji Restoration was led by a
bourgeoisie in the process of becoming. This understanding was expressed in one
of the earliest Soviet studies of the subject, written in 1920:
“We may conclude that Japan, having changed its economical
structure, still did not possess the class of bourgeoisie which could take over
the rule of the country. It was the class of feudal lords that remained in
power. They acknowledged the changes which had happened in Japan, rejected all
outmoded feudal norms and started the rapid development of capitalism.... Hence,
the term ‘revolution’ may be used in relation to the Meiji Ishin only
conventionally. It may be called ‘bourgeois’ only from the viewpoint of its
results, which does not mean at all that the bourgeoisie played the most
important role at that time.”
— O.V. Pletner, The History of the Meiji Era, quoted in
Julia Mikhailova, “Soviet-Japanese Studies on the Problem of the Meiji Ishin and
the Development of Capitalism in Japan,” in War, Revolution and Japan
(1993)
A Bourgeois-Democratic Revolution Was Precluded by History
For Marxists, a bourgeois-democratic revolution is centrally
defined by its socio-economic (i.e., class) content, not by a
change in the form of government. The classic bourgeois-democratic revolutions
in England in the 1640s and France in 1789-93 overthrew absolutist monarchies
that were the political organs of the landed nobility. Mobilizing the peasantry
and urban lower classes, the mercantile (i.e., pre-industrial) bourgeoisie
achieved political power through the Cromwellian Commonwealth in England and the
Jacobin regime and later Napoleonic empire in France.
To view the classic bourgeois-democratic revolutions as a template
for all subsequent capitalist development—as did the Mensheviks in their stagist
schema for tsarist Russia, and subsequently Stalin/Bukharin in the case of the
semicolonial countries—is ahistorical and undialectical. When in
July 1789 artisans, shopkeepers and day laborers in Paris stormed the Bastille,
France was the strongest absolutist (i.e., late feudal) state in Europe. The
revolution greatly enhanced the economic and military resources of the French
state, enabling Napoleon Bonaparte—a onetime protégé of Robespierre—to conquer
and transform much of Europe. The masses had to be mobilized to break a path for
capitalist development in France (and earlier in England). This was also
partially true in a somewhat later period in the United States and Italy. But it
is not true for Germany or Japan. There is no necessary connection between
democracy and the development of capitalism.
The “bourgeois revolutions from above” in late 19th-century Germany
and Japan were not exceptions to some historic “norm” set by the French
Revolution. They were instead the outcome of the intervening history since the
French Revolution. The only way for the ruling classes in Germany and Japan to
avoid invasion and subjugation by Britain, France or the United States was rapid
industrialization. They were able to propel their nations into the ranks of the
imperialist powers by clearing out the feudal obstacles to capitalist
development from above, in the process transforming themselves into capitalists.
By 1900, with the world and its markets more or less divided between the five
existing imperialist powers, that road was closed to other late developing
bourgeoisies.
Japan in the mid 19th century was a pre-industrial
(though in many ways relatively advanced) feudal state confronting far more
powerful industrializing capitalist states. It was the well-grounded fear of
succumbing to China’s fate that galvanized decisive sections of the Japanese
feudal nobility, especially the lower echelons of the samurai, to
overthrow the old order and restructure the Japanese economy and state along
Western lines. Though he himself viewed the Meiji Restoration as an “incomplete”
bourgeois revolution, E. Herbert Norman also understood that the conditions
confronting the Meiji rulers immediately after the revolution ruled out a
bourgeois-democratic road:
“The speed with which Japan had simultaneously to
establish a modern state, to build an up-to-date defense force in order to ward
off the dangers of invasion (which the favorable balance of world forces and the
barrier of China could not forever postpone), to create an industry on which to
base this armed force, to fashion an educational system suitable to an
industrial modernized nation, dictated that these important changes be
accomplished by a group of autocratic bureaucrats rather than by the mass of the
people working through democratic organs of representation.”
—Op. cit.
Could this social transformation have been accomplished by a
revolutionary upheaval? Let us assume that the civil war between the
Bakufu and the tozama had resulted in the mutual destruction or
disorganization of any effective military force in the hands of the feudal
nobility. A power vacuum formed, allowing a mass peasant rebellion, refusal to
pay tribute to the daimyo, and also uprisings of the lower classes in the
cities. In short, Japan was engulfed by revolutionary anarchy.
What would have been the historical outcome? The Japanese
daimyo and shonin would have invited and facilitated the military
intervention of the Western powers to suppress the peasant rebellion. In the
aftermath Japan would have been reduced to colonial or semicolonial subjugation.
A section of the daimyo, samurai and merchant class would have
been transformed into a comprador bourgeoisie, such as then existed in China,
totally subservient to the Western imperialists.
One need only look at the Taiping rebellion in China in the 1850s
and early 1860s. This massive peasant revolt, which lasted over a decade, took
over much of the Yangtze Valley and established a capital in the major city of
Nanjing. Since the decadent Manchu rulers were incapable of suppressing the
revolt, the Chinese gentry (landlord class) turned to the Western powers. An
American adventurer, Frederick Townsend Ward, and a British officer, Charles
“Chinese” Gordon, trained and commanded an elite Chinese force which finally
defeated the Taipings.
A peasant rebellion in Japan at this time, even if initially
successful, would have suffered a similar fate. This is not to say that
following the Meiji Restoration the future course of Japanese history was
predetermined for the next several decades. Some greater degree of social
egalitarianism and political liberalization was certainly possible in late 19th-
and early 20th-century Japan. But what was not possible was a radical
bourgeois-democratic revolution on the French model.
The 1873 Land Tax
The leaders of the Meiji Restoration expressed their intent to
modernize Japan with such slogans as “Prosperous Nation, Strong Military” and
“Increase Production, Promote Industry.” But how were these slogans translated
into reality, given that Japan at the time was far more economically backward
than the Western capitalist states that threatened its independence? In brief,
by maintaining an exceptionally high level of exploitation of the peasantry, but
now channeling the resulting economic surplus into the rapid construction of an
industrial-military complex. The 1873 Land Tax was the main mechanism in late
19th-century Japan for what Marx termed, in speaking of West Europe (centrally
England) in the 17th and 18th centuries, the “primitive accumulation of
capital.”
In 1871, the new Meiji regime, through a combination of military
threat and financial inducement, pressured the daimyo into “returning”
their han to the authority of the central government. They were
compensated with long-term government bonds. At the same time, the government
took over the stipends, though at a diminishing rate, which the former
daimyo had paid to their samurai. The Land Tax provided the bulk
of the revenue for the interest and redeemed principal on the government bonds
as well as the stipends to the former samurai.
In this way, the state treasury became a conduit between the
economic surplus extracted from the peasantry and a developing
industrial/financial bourgeoisie drawn from the former feudal nobility and the
old merchant class. By 1880, 44 percent of the stock of Japan’s national banks
was owned by former daimyo, and almost a third by former samurai.
These banks then went on to finance the rapid development of Japanese
industry.
The central role played by the state treasury in the initial
industrialization of Japan also resulted, paradoxically, from the restrictions
imposed upon Japanese economic policy by the Western imperialist powers. Under
the threat of American and British military action, in the late 1850s and ’60s
the Tokugawa shogunate signed unequal commercial treaties which prohibited Japan
from charging tariffs of more than 5 percent of the value of Western imports.
The Meiji government was therefore unable to protect its newly developing
industries behind high tariff barriers, as Germany and the United States were
able to do in the late 19th century. Instead the Japanese ruling class had
recourse to direct government ownership and subsidies.
American economic historian G.C. Allen stated: “There was scarcely
any important Japanese industry of the Western type during the latter decades of
the nineteenth century which did not owe its establishment to state initiative”
(A Short Economic History of Modern Japan [1981]). By the end of the
century, almost all state-owned industrial enterprises and other assets had been
sold off, usually at nominal prices, to politically favored entrepreneurs. The
most successful of these formed the zaibatsu, the great
industrial/financial empires like Mitsubishi and Mitsui which came to dominate
and continue to dominate the Japanese economy.
Just as Meiji Japan saw the rise of a new class of
industrial/financial capitalists, it also saw the rise of a new class of
agrarian exploiters. As increasing numbers of peasants were unable to meet their
tax payments and/or repay their debts at usurious interest rates, they were
forced to sell all or part of their land, typically to rich peasants or village
merchant/moneylenders. Many were forced to send their daughters to work for
textile manufacturers in the city, thus providing workers for early Japanese
industry. An advance on the daughters’ wages would be loaned to the peasant
families to meet their tax burden. Interest and principal on these loans,
together with payments for the daughters’ food and lodging, consumed most of, if
not more than the wages, forcing rural families further into debt. By 1903, 44
percent of all agricultural land in Japan was worked by tenant farmers who paid
over 50 percent of their crop, usually in kind, as rent to the landlords.
Here it should be emphasized that the landlord class in early
20th-century Japan was not in the main derived from the old feudal
nobility. An American student of Japanese agrarian history explained:
“Although most former daimyo remained wealthy and as members of
the House of Peers gained a direct voice in the political system after 1890,
they were no longer a landed aristocracy with the power to control local
affairs.... They invested in forest land, in new industrial enterprises, and
perhaps most of all, in banking. Even if part of their income was derived from
agriculture, it was generally a small part, overshadowed by their other
interests. They no longer exercised political control over the land they owned,
and although they were represented in the House of Peers, that body was at no
time the center of political power.”
— Ann Waswo, Japanese Landlords: The Decline of a Rural
Elite (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977)
The lower house of the Diet, which approved the government budget,
was elected by the wealthiest male property owners.
A new landlord class arose through the economic
differentiation of the peasantry and other sectors of the rural petty
bourgeoisie. In the 1930s, a visiting American academic contemptuously described
typical Japanese landlords as “lately merchants, owners of inns and brothels,
masters of road repair crews, and persons of similar status” (quoted in
ibid.). Furthermore, wealthier landlords increasingly reinvested the
rents collected from tenant farmers in bank deposits, government bonds and
corporate securities. By the 1920s, the wealthiest families in rural Japan were
getting as much, if not more, of their income from their financial assets as
from their agricultural holdings.
Thus the landlord class in interwar Japan was in no sense feudal or
semi-feudal, but was thoroughly integrated economically and in many cases
socially into the dominant urban industrial economy.
The 1889 Meiji Constitution
While the Meiji Restoration was a revolution from above, it
necessarily produced powerful reverberations from below, awakening among the
peasants and urban laborers expectations of a better and freer life. The two
decades following were a period of great social and political turbulence.
For the first time in Japanese history, women rebelled against
their traditional subservience and demanded democratic rights. Several villages
and municipalities set up local councils, and women were allowed to run for
office (provided they had their husbands’ permission). Women militants toured
the country giving speeches calling for suffrage, birth control and the right of
inheritance.
The forces of social radicalism found their main organized
expression in the People’s Rights Movement, which demanded a democratic,
representative government. Rural agitation centered around this movement
climaxed in 1884, in a rebellion in the mountainous district of Chichibu in
central Japan, northwest of Tokyo. Peasants sacked the homes of moneylenders,
stormed government offices to destroy debt records, and intimidated the rich
into making donations for poor relief. The uprising was crushed by the army and
shortly thereafter the People’s Rights Movement was broken through a combination
of state repression and the government’s success in buying off many of its
leaders.
The consolidation of a strong repressive state apparatus laid the
political basis for the 1889 Meiji Constitution, which was modeled on that of
imperial Germany. Government ministers were appointed by the emperor (actually
by the Meiji oligarchs acting in the emperor’s name), not by the majority party
in the Diet.
Taking the concept of ie (family household system) as the
basis for the new hierarchical social structure, the 1898 Civil Code adopted the
Confucian-based values of the samurai class as its foundation. The
emperor stood at the apex as the head of the entire nation and, in turn, the
husband was absolute ruler over his individual family. Primogeniture was
mandated for all classes. Wives were treated as minors, and the code insisted
that “cripples and disabled persons and wives cannot undertake any legal
action.” Women were banned from participating in political activities. Yet women
workers were the backbone of the developing industrial economy—especially in the
textile industry, which produced 60 percent of the foreign exchange in the
latter part of the 19th century and in which women made up 60 to 90 percent of
the workforce.
The emperor system enshrined in the constitution was
not a surviving feudal institution representing the interests of a
landed nobility (which no longer existed at all). Rather, the traditional
authority and mystical aura surrounding the emperor were now used to legitimize
a state apparatus which first and foremost acted to protect and further the
interests of the industrial and financial capitalists, represented at their apex
by the zaibatsu.
World War I and Industrialization
The First World War changed the structure of the Japanese economy
and working class, while the 1917 Russian Bolshevik Revolution changed the
political character of the Japanese left. Prior to 1914 Japan’s heavy industrial
sector, closely tied to the military, remained dependent on government financial
support. Japan exported light manufactures—mainly cotton textiles and silk—and
imported industrial machinery and much of its steel from Europe and the United
States.
The war totally disrupted the existing pattern of world trade,
enabling Japan to move up into the first rank of industrial capitalist
countries. A Japanese academic Marxist, Takahashi Masao, pointed out:
“With the European nations devoting themselves entirely to the war
effort, the arteries of commodity exchange in the world economy were completely
stopped....
“Although there was a great difference in the scope and degree of
industrialization, both America and Japan were able to rapidly and extensively
develop their economies. They were in a similar position in that they were both
able to develop those kinds of manufacturing for which they had previously been
dependent on Europe. And thus they functioned as suppliers of industrial
products for underdeveloped areas, as well as of goods of various kinds for the
belligerent nations.”
— Modern Japanese Economy Since the Meiji Restoration
(1967)
Between 1914 and 1921, Japan’s output of steel doubled; the
production of electrical motors increased in value from 9 million to 34 million
yen. Overall, industrial production multiplied almost
fivefold!
This brought about a corresponding change in the social weight and
character of the Japanese working class. The proportion of the manufacturing
labor force engaged in heavy industry, characterized by large-scale factories,
increased from 13.6 percent in 1910 to 24.2 percent by the end of the war. In
the early 1920s there was a large permanently urbanized industrial proletariat
in Japan, heavily male, employed in steel mills, shipyards, chemical factories,
auto and truck plants, etc. Nonetheless, Japan was the only major industrial
capitalist country in the interwar period in which peasant struggle against
landlords was an important arena of social conflict.
The changes in workforce composition combined with the inflation
that accompanied the World War I industrial expansion resulted in an upsurge in
labor militancy and social unrest, capped by the 1918 “Rice Riots.” The price of
rice doubled from 1917 to 1918, and after the wives of fishermen in Toyama
Prefecture raided rice shops in August 1918, rice riots spread throughout the
country. The government called out troops to quell the riots, killing more than
100 protesters. The surge of unrest led to a mass movement for universal
suffrage. The poll tax was decreased in 1919 (increasing the voter rolls from
one to three million), but the government refused to grant universal suffrage.
Strikes and labor unrest also spread, and Japanese socialists began to gain
influence in some major Japanese unions.
Early Japanese Communists
Early Japanese Socialists were largely Christian and confined to
small propaganda groups. After 1906 an anarcho-syndicalist current developed,
but its membership periodically collaborated with the more reformist-minded
Socialist movement. In 1910 the best-known anarchist, Kotoku Shusui, and 26
supporters were arrested and charged with plotting to assassinate the emperor
and his family. Following the so-called Great Treason Trial, Kotoku was executed
in 1911, along with eleven others, including his companion Kanno Suga. After
this the organized left virtually ceased to exist.
Katayama Sen, a leader of the evolutionary, pacifist wing of
Japanese socialism, had previously spent time in the United States and returned
there in 1914. There he worked with the Socialist Party, took a special interest
in the fight against black oppression, and eventually founded the League of
Japanese Socialists. Won to the Bolshevik banner after the Russian Revolution,
Katayama sent many League members back to Japan to help found a Japanese
Communist Party. He himself went to Moscow in late 1921, playing a major role in
the Comintern’s dealings with Japan from 1922. However, the extent to which
Katayama broke from his Christian, pacifist origins remains questionable. During
the Stalinist degeneration he espoused the bureaucracy’s various twists and
turns with unfailing loyalty. In 1928 Trotsky wrote, “Katayama is by nature a
complete mistake.... His conceptions form a progressivism very lightly colored
by Marxism” (“Who Is Leading the Comintern Today?”, September 1928).
Nevertheless, the supporters he won in the United States played an important
role in the early Japanese Communist movement.
The core leadership of the early JCP, however, came from the
anarcho-syndicalists like Yamakawa Hitoshi, Sakai Toshihiko and Arahata Kanson,
who began to propagate Bolshevism (as they understood it) as early as May 1919.
They were joined not only by Katayama’s supporters, but also by individual
student recruits from a burgeoning post-World War I academic Marxist trend that
was tolerated by the government for most of the decade. Despite the authority
won by anarcho-syndicalists in the union movement after the war, the early
Communists had very slim roots in the working class.
Japan was the first imperialist country to invade the territory of
the world’s first workers state in April 1918. Its troops were the last to leave
in November 1922, and even then Japan retained control of Sakhalin Island,
agreeing to evacuate its troops from Northern Sakhalin only in 1925, when
diplomatic relations with Soviet Russia were finally established. Japan
continued to occupy Southern Sakhalin until its troops were driven out by the
Red Army at the end of World War II.
While the Bolsheviks made efforts to establish contact with
Japanese militants attracted to the Russian Revolution’s banner, foreign
military intervention and the Civil War, which raged in the Russian Far East,
made such contact extremely difficult. Moreover, Yamakawa and Sakai were
originally reticent to establish contact with the Comintern, fearing to draw the
attention of the very efficient Japanese secret police. It was not until April
1921, when the Korean Communist Yi Chung-rim, who had been a student at Meiji
University, was sent to Tokyo by the CI that Yamakawa agreed to establish a
“Preparatory Committee” for a Japanese Communist Party. At this point the
Japanese Communists constituted a loose circle that overlapped with the
anarcho-syndicalists.
The opening of the Comintern Archives in Moscow has made available
a wealth of new material on the Japanese Communist Party, which sheds light on
the early years of the party. We publish three of the newly available JCP
documents as appendices to this article, including the April 1921 Manifesto of
the Preparatory Committee of the JCP, which was authored by Yamakawa, working
with Katayama protégé Kondo Eizo. The 1921 Manifesto makes clear that the early
Japanese Communists considered the Meiji Restoration to have laid the basis for
a capitalist Japan and did not subscribe to a two-stage schema.
The first delegation from the Japanese Socialist/anarchist milieu
did not arrive in Moscow until late 1921. They came to participate in the First
Congress of the Toilers of the Far East, which took place in January-February
1922. The Congress included not only Communists, but also bourgeois-nationalist
forces (the Chinese Guomindang was present), journalists and other disparate
forces. Bukharin, Zinoviev and Stalin were appointed by the Russian Political
Bureau to be the Commission in charge of directing the Congress. Zinoviev
convened the event and played a very public role there. Bukharin helped draft
and present the resolution on Japan. Stalin met with the Japanese delegation and
is credited in at least one account with being among those who won over some of
the anarcho-syndicalists. Stalin retained his interest in the Far East for the
rest of the decade, and it is clear that he worked closely with Bukharin in
developing the “two-stage revolution” dogma and pushing it upon the Communist
parties of the East.
The Congress was held on the eve of Lenin’s first stroke and just
as Stalin, Zinoviev and Kamenev were beginning to establish their alliance
against Trotsky. The Zinovievist school of politics as bombast and maneuver was
infecting the Comintern. However, it had not yet triumphed. The “Tasks of the
Japanese Communists” adopted at the Congress clearly states, “A proletarian
dictatorship, the replacement of the military-plutocratic monarchy with the
power of the Soviets—that is the goal of the Communist Party.” At the same time,
the resolution asserted that “the configuration of class forces in Japan allows
us to expect the success of a radical democratic overturn” and argued that the
JCP orient itself accordingly.
The resolutions and proceedings of the First Congress of the
Toilers of the Far East introduced certain ambiguities into the tasks of the
Asian Communist parties, but this was by no means a full-blown schema of
“two-stage revolution.” The CI leadership did not recognize that the disruption
of trade with Europe during WWI had led, not just to an expansion of Japan’s
industrial base, but also to the development of a burgeoning industrial
proletariat in colonial and semicolonial countries like China and India. Thus,
the main report on the national-colonial question, delivered by G. Safarov, was
based on the premise that the proletariat in most Eastern countries did not have
the social weight to play a leading role in a revolutionary upsurge. Japan was
recognized as an exception to this pattern—a full-blown imperialist country with
a proletariat which was the key to liberating the entire East. Safarov insisted
that the Japanese proletariat must ally itself with the nations struggling to
liberate themselves from Japanese imperialism. He called for the absolute
political independence of the proletariat from the bourgeois-nationalist forces
with whom they might collaborate.
The JCP and “Two-Stage Revolution”
The Japanese Communist Party was formally founded in July 1922,
some six months after the Congress of the Toilers of the Far East completed its
work. One month later, in August 1922, the Comintern made the decision that the
young Communist Party of China should enter the Guomindang. Three months later,
in November, during the Fourth Congress of the Communist International, Bukharin
authored a draft program of the Japanese party which did not mention the Meiji
Restoration, let alone seek to evaluate its import. He wrote:
“Japanese capitalism still demonstrates characteristics of former
feudal relationships. The greater part of the land is today in the hands of
semifeudal big landlords....
“Remnants of feudal relationships are manifested in the structure
of the state, which is controlled by a bloc consisting of a definite part of the
commercial and industrial capitalists and of the big landlords. The semifeudal
character of state power is clearly shown in the important and leading role of
the peers and in the basic features of the constitution. Under such conditions
the opposition to state power emanates not only from the working class,
peasants, and petty bourgeoisie, but also from a great segment of the
liberalistic bourgeoisie, who are opposed to the existing government.”
— “Draft Platform of the Japanese Communist Party,” November 1922,
published in George M. Beckmann and Okubo Genji, The Japanese Communist
Party, 1922-1945 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1969)
The program went on to insist:
“The party of the working class cannot remain indifferent to a
struggle against the imperial government, even though such a struggle may be
conducted under democratic slogans. The task of the Communist Party is to
constantly intensify the general movement, emphasize all slogans, and win the
dominant position in the movement during the struggle against the existing
government.
“Only after this first direct task has been fulfilled and some of
the former allies have begun to move to the side of the defeated class and
groups should the Japanese Communist Party strive to advance the revolution,
deepen it, and make efforts toward the acquisition of power by soviets of
workers and peasants.”
—Ibid.
The standard histories of Japanese Communism do not mention,
however, that there was another draft JCP program written two months prior to
Bukharin’s. This draft (published as an appendix here) was authored in
Japan by Arahata and Sakai. Arahata and Sakai label Japan “the Germany
of the East,” and their program begins with the clear statement that “The
Communist Party of Japan, a section of the Third Communist International, is an
illegal, proletarian political party, whose aim is the overthrow of the
Capitalist regime through the establishment of the Dictatorship of the
Proletariat based on the Soviet Power.” There is not a hint of stagism here.
Bukharin’s draft treats the democratic program it puts forward as a
temporary agenda for the Communist Party during the struggle to overthrow the
“existing government”—as if by draping itself in democratic clothing the JCP
could fool a wing of the rabidly anti-Communist Japanese bourgeoisie into
collaborating with it! The Arahata and Sakai draft, in contrast, correctly (if
abstractly) calls for combining the struggle for bourgeois-democratic rights
with the struggle for proletarian revolution to overthrow the capitalist system
as a whole.
Bukharin’s 1922 draft was greeted with significant opposition in
the JCP and was never officially adopted by the party. We publish as our third
appendix a May 1923 report by Arahata, written for the Third Enlarged Plenum of
the Comintern Executive Committee (ECCI) held in June, which describes the
dispute that developed in the JCP over Bukharin’s draft. This report was
published in Russian in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan, 1917-1941
and to our knowledge has not previously been available to students of Japanese
Communism.
As is apparent from Arahata’s report, at least some of the
opposition to Bukharin’s draft was due to residual anarcho-syndicalist
prejudices. Active in a series of increasingly violent strikes in 1921 and 1922,
the JCP continued to collaborate with the anarcho-syndicalists in the Sodomei,
the main trade-union federation. The cadre who went on to form the JCP had
ignored the struggle for universal suffrage; the question of whether or not to
even support the suffrage demand was under debate in the party as late as the
end of 1923 (when Yamakawa finally abandoned his opposition to it). Reformist
impulses were apparently also in play: Sakai at least did not want to raise the
demand for the abolition of the emperor system, fearing that this would bring
down further state repression on the young party.
It is clear from newly available Comintern documents that the
disparate forces that came together to form the JCP never gelled into a real
collective. The early debate between the pro-Bolshevik and anarcho-syndicalist
elements was never fought out to a conclusion; nor was the dispute on universal
suffrage ever resolved. The decisive lesson of the Russian Revolution—the need
for a programmatically homogenous party of professional revolutionaries—was
clearly not assimilated by the early JCP leaders. The party did not have a
central organ which carried the party’s line; the closest thing was
Zen’ei (Vanguard) which carried only signed articles and was seen as
Yamakawa’s personal responsibility. Personal animosities often overlapped with
political disputes and muddied the issues. The young JCP desperately needed
education and help in fighting through its differences and forging a political
line and cadre committed to implement it. But in 1922-23 the CI was already
beginning its slide toward degeneration and did not provide the kind of
political clarity that had been given to the young and fractious American
Communist movement from 1919-1922 (see James P. Cannon and the Early Years of
American Communism: Selected Writings and Speeches, 1920-1928 [New York:
Prometheus Research Library, 1992]).
While Japan was not “semi-feudal,” the undemocratic nature of its
transition from feudalism to capitalism continued to reverberate in a myriad of
ways. The government promised to introduce universal male suffrage at the end of
1923; the law wasn’t promulgated until 1925 and then the vote was only granted
to males over the age of 25. At the same time, there was an
increase in repressive measures. The 1925 Peace Preservation Law
made it illegal to participate in any organization with the “objective of
altering the national polity or the form of government, or denying the system of
private ownership” (quoted in Beckmann and Okubo, op. cit.). A resolution
of the Privy Council motivated the new law: “Since putting universal suffrage
into effect will result in a worsening of dangerous ideas, the government must
establish and put into effect laws and regulations for the rigid control [of
dangerous ideas] and must exert itself to prevent evil abuses and practices”
(quoted in Peter Duus, Party Rivalry and Political Change in Taisho Japan
[1968]). The Peace Preservation Law was the legal basis for the vicious
repression against the JCP through WWII.
With the feudal legacy shaping so many aspects of the Japanese
bourgeois order, the weight of democratic demands is necessarily greater in the
proletarian revolutionary program. From its inception in 1988 the Spartacist
Group Japan has called for the abolition of the emperor system and the
establishment of a workers republic in Japan (our British section also calls for
the abolition of the monarchy and a federation of workers republics in the
British Isles). Unfortunately, the idea of a workers republic, a slogan which
had been raised by the Irish revolutionary James Connolly as early as 1898,
seems to have been absent from the lexicon of the early Communist
International.
The CI’s “Workers and Peasants Party” Orientation and the JCP’s
Liquidation
The political lines were muddied further in 1923 by the CI
leadership’s insistence that the JCP form a legal “workers and peasants” party,
which was to include representatives of the liberal bourgeoisie. This was part
of a general orientation toward such parties, including in the U.S., pushed by
the Comintern under Zinoviev’s leadership. The model of such a workers and
peasants party was Chiang Kai-shek’s bourgeois-nationalist Guomindang (a version
of which the CI leadership was proposing for Japan), which drowned the Chinese
Revolution of 1925-27 in blood.
From the start, Trotsky fought the “two-class” party perspective.
In 1928, he subjected the misleadership of the world Communist movement to a
scathing and comprehensive attack in his Critique of the Comintern draft program
written by Bukharin. Trotsky’s Critique, a defining document of world Trotskyism
now known as The Third International After Lenin, contains an important
section, “On the Reactionary Idea of ‘Two-Class Workers and Peasants Parties’
for the Orient”:
“Marxism has always taught, and Bolshevism too, accepted and
taught, that the peasantry and proletariat are two different classes, that it is
false to identify their interests in capitalist society in any way, and that a
peasant can join the Communist Party only if, from the property viewpoint, he
adopts the views of the proletariat....
“The younger the proletariat, the fresher and more direct its
‘blood ties’ with the peasantry, the greater the proportion of the peasantry to
the population as a whole, the greater becomes the importance of the struggle
against any form of ‘two-class’ political alchemy. In the West the idea of a
workers and peasants party is simply ridiculous. In the East it is fatal. In
China, India, and Japan this idea is mortally hostile not only to the hegemony
of the proletariat in the revolution but also to the most elementary
independence of the proletarian vanguard.”
Arahata spoke on the floor of the June 1923 ECCI Plenum against the
perspective of forming a legal workers and peasants party in Japan. Zinoviev
responded, “We shall insist that our Japanese comrades learn a lesson from the
American Communist Party, and try to organize a legal Communist party in Japan.”
The American Communist movement had gone underground in response to a wave of
arrests and deportations in 1919-20 known as the “Palmer Raids,” but conditions
quickly returned to the norms of bourgeois democracy as the American ruling
class figured out that its rule was not fundamentally threatened. The legal
party formed by the American Communists in December 1921 was the Workers Party,
which had an openly communist program. (The American Workers Party also went on
to follow CI directives in 1923 and join in the founding of a short-lived
Farmer-Labor Party on a populist program.)
Replying to Zinoviev, Arahata correctly argued, “The case of the
American Party is not the same as with us.... Our Party is a secret organization
not because we want underground work but the situation compels us to be so”
(transcript of Arahata’s speech on 14 June 1923, in the Comintern archives in
the Russian State Archive of Socio-Political History). Japan in 1923 was not a
bourgeois democracy nor about to become one. The government promised to
introduce expanded suffrage that year, but the first election held under
universal (male) suffrage didn’t occur until 1928. A legal Communist Party was
not possible. Indeed, a legal party could not even call for abolition of the
emperor system.
As if to mock Zinoviev’s fatuous remark, the Japanese government
struck out with a wave of arrests of Japanese Communists in June 1923, on the
eve of a meeting between Soviet diplomat Adolf Joffe and Japanese government
representatives in Tokyo. The severe repression cut short the discussion of
Bukharin’s draft program. Joffe had been careful not to get involved with the
JCP (the Bolshevik leadership had evolved a correct and necessary separation
between the Comintern’s revolutionary activities and the diplomacy of the Soviet
state). But the arrests were obviously meant as a statement of hostility to any
red influence in Japan. At the time, powerful bourgeois circles opposed all
negotiations with the Soviet state. Though Joffe remained in Tokyo for several
more months, his negotiations were unsuccessful.
A few leading Japanese Communists were able to escape arrest and
get out of Japan, establishing a Japanese Bureau in Vladivostok in August 1923
with the approval of the Comintern. In fact, an émigré center was a vital
continuing necessity for the JCP. The party needed a leadership collective out
of reach of the Japanese state in order to produce a regular newspaper in
Japanese, as the Russian revolutionary Marxists had in an earlier period
published the newspaper Iskra (Spark) and the theoretical journal
Zarya (Dawn) to smuggle into the tsarist empire from European exile. A
stable JCP exile center would have been able to organize political debate,
collect information, and keep contact with those working underground in Japan.
Constant political debate over the real work of the party is a crucial aspect of
forging revolutionary communist parties.
However, the CI Japanese Bureau had barely begun functioning when a
horrific earthquake devastated much of Tokyo on 1 September 1923. In its wake,
the country was shaken by pogroms in which over 6,000 Koreans and hundreds of
Chinese were massacred. Communists, anarchists and labor leaders were hunted
down and killed; some were murdered in police stations. A wave of arrests of
leftist and labor leaders followed. In the aftermath, the Comintern made the
criminal decision to order most of the Japanese cadre in Vladivostok back to
Japan, thereby liquidating the Japanese Bureau and ending any chance of
establishing a stable political and organizational basis for the JCP.
At that time, all the attention of the CI leaders was focused on a
potential proletarian revolution in Germany. Those who made the decision to
liquidate the Japanese Bureau, knowing the full extent of the carnage and
arrests in Japan, wantonly neglected the need to create and preserve a
programmatically coherent JCP leadership like that which had been forged in
exile by the Russian Marxists, first under Plekhanov, and later by the
Bolsheviks under Lenin. More concerned with Soviet diplomatic initiatives than
preserving the JCP leadership, G. Voitinsky of the CI’s Eastern Bureau sent a
directive to the party that concluded:
“The drawing together of Japan and Soviet Russia after the
catastrophe must be made the most popular slogan among the masses of Japan,
since it is only from Soviet Russia that unselfish aid can come in the form of
raw materials needed for Japanese production. The party must pose the drawing
together of Japan and Russia as the alternative to the economic and political
enslavement of Japan by Anglo-American capital.”
— “Directive Telegram by G. Voitinsky to JCP,” 14 September 1923,
published in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan, 1917-1941 (our
translation)
The Japanese cadre were sent back to Japan with no confidence that
they would have an impact. The ECCI representative to the Japanese Bureau, I.I.
Feinberg, wrote:
“I believe that activists are better sent to work in the country
than kept idle in Vladivostok.
“From the information that we do have it is clear that the
earthquake is fraught with the most severe economic consequences and will place
Japan into dependence on foreign capital.... We need to take this fact into
account in our policies. I believe that the instructions we prepared work
towards this end. The only question is how to realize them. Speaking frankly, I
don’t have any great optimism. Our forces in Japan are still quite weak and
inexperienced, so it doesn’t make sense to expect very much from them.”
— “Letter by I.I. Feinberg to G.N. Voitinsky,” 20 September 1923,
published in ibid. (our translation)
This criminal decision set the JCP up to be destroyed by repeated
waves of state repression.
The Japanese Communists, many of whom were released from prison
just before the earthquake hit, were in no position to lead any kind of public
campaign. The arrests had devastated the tiny party; the earthquake’s
destruction compounded the problems (for example, the party’s illegal press was
destroyed).
Instead of following the CI’s instructions to increase their public
activity, the leading Japanese Communists made a decision to
liquidate the JCP in favor of concentrating their efforts on
forming a legal workers and peasants party. Yamakawa, who seems to have done a
political about-face at this time, abandoning his remaining anarcho-syndicalist
prejudices in favor of the fight for universal suffrage and a parliamentarist
approach, was the ideological inspirer of the liquidation. The JCP was formally
liquidated in March 1924; it was not reconstituted until December 1926. In the
interim the Japanese Communist movement functioned in loosely coordinated
circles, overlapping with the academic Marxist milieu, but under the ostensible
direction of a central bureau.
The Comintern opposed the liquidation of the JCP from the moment
the news reached Moscow. Katayama and other CI leaders mobilized to organize
Yamakawa’s opponents (among whom numbered, at least initially, Arahata) to
re-establish the JCP. But the liquidation was simply the logical political
conclusion of Zinoviev’s insistence that the JCP concentrate on legal political
activity in the form of a workers and peasants party. During the period of
liquidation the Japanese Communists—both the supporters of Yamakawa and the
supporters of the CI—joined the Japan Peasant Union and Sodomei trade-union
federation in forming two workers and peasants parties. The first was dissolved
by the government immediately after it was founded. The second, Rodo Nominto
(Labor-Farmer Party), was formed in March 1926. The reformist Sodomei leadership
withdrew from Rodo Nominto within months, refusing to cooperate any longer with
the Communists, and formed its own farmer- labor party. This left Rodo Nominto
as a legal, “democratic” front group of the Communists. Yamakawa and Sakai were
active in Rodo Nominto, even as they refused to join in any efforts to
reconstitute the JCP.
Continued Controversy over Meiji Restoration and “Two-Stage
Revolution”
The controversy over Bukharin’s 1922 draft was never formally
resolved; nonetheless, the two-stage schema was adopted as the official program
of the JCP. Even so, the nature of the Meiji Restoration and the coming
revolution in Japan continued to be a source of controversy. Fukumoto Kazuo, who
gained leadership of the Japanese Communist movement in 1926-27, argued that the
Japanese Constitution of 1889 (not the Meiji Restoration) constituted Japan’s
bourgeois-democratic revolution, though this “was artfully concealed from the
masses.” Fukumoto correctly noted that the Japanese bourgeoisie had turned
reactionary, and he asserted that the Japanese state “has today developed in
itself the germ of fascist dictatorship.” Too much of an independent mind for
Moscow’s liking, Fukumoto was deposed, falsely accused of being a
“Trotskyist.”
In 1927 new programmatic theses on Japan were adopted by the
Comintern. Again this was authored by Bukharin. This lengthy and contradictory
document argued: “The revolution of 1868 opened the path for capitalist
development in Japan. Political power, however, remained in the hands of the
feudal elements.” Bukharin now had to admit that the period since the Meiji
Restoration had seen “the transformation of the old Japanese state into a
bourgeois state.” In contradistinction to the 1922 draft program, he wrote that
“Japan is governed by a bloc of the bourgeoisie and landlords—a bloc under the
hegemony of the bourgeoisie. This being so, illusions that the bourgeoisie can
in any way be utilized as a revolutionary factor, even during the first stage of
the bourgeois-democratic revolution, must be abandoned” (“Theses on Japan
Adopted in the Session of the Presidium of the Executive Committee of the
Comintern on July 15, 1927,” in Beckmann and Okubo, op.cit.). Yet the
1927 theses still set as the aim of the JCP a bourgeois-democratic revolution
which would “rapidly grow into a socialist revolution”!
The 1927 theses provoked an open split with founding Communists
Yamakawa, Sakai and Arahata, who formed the Rono-ha (Labor-Farmer Faction). They
opposed the two-stage schema, insisting that the coming revolution in Japan
would be a proletarian one. But far from being a left opposition to Stalinist
opportunism, the Rono-ha faction insisted that the activity of Japanese
Communists be limited to legal work under the guise of a workers and peasants
party. The debate between Rono-ha and what became known as Koza-ha (the official
pro-Moscow party) on the development and nature of Japanese capitalism went on
for years and encompassed thousands of pages. But it is clear that Rono-ha’s
insistence that the bourgeoisie ruled in Japan, while correct, was largely a
theoretical justification for its refusal to call for the abolition of the
emperor system or engage in any other illegal activity. Acknowledging Rono-ha’s
willingness to stay within the limits set by the Japanese bourgeoisie, the state
allowed Rono-ha supporters to function legally until 1937, while savagely
repressing the JCP. Arahata and Yamakawa played leading roles in forming the
Japanese Socialist Party under the U.S. Occupation in 1945 (Sakai died in
1933).
Even after the split with Rono-ha, the question of a stagist
perspective was not settled within the JCP. In 1931, after Stalin had purged
Bukharin from the CI leadership and embarked on the sectarian adventurism and
left posturing of the Third Period, the JCP developed new programmatic theses
which described the Meiji Restoration as “a bourgeois-democratic revolution that
paved the way for the development of capitalism” and argued that the coming
Japanese revolution would be a “proletarian revolution that involves extensive
bourgeois-democratic tasks” (“The Political Theses of the Japanese Communist
Party, April-June 1931,” ibid.).
The hint of clarity provided by the 1931 theses did not, however,
last very long. Frightened by the Japanese invasion of Manchuria, the Stalinist
bureaucrats in the Kremlin refused to give up the illusion that a more
Soviet-friendly bourgeois regime could come to exist in Japan. The CI demanded
that the 1931 theses be thrown out. New theses on Japan adopted in 1932 argued
for the “overthrow of the monarchy by the victorious people’s revolution,” after
which “the main task of the Communist Party will be the struggle for the rapid
development of the bourgeois-democratic revolution into a socialist revolution”
(“Theses on the Situation in Japan and the Tasks of the Communist Party, May
1932,” ibid.). By this time, state persecution had so devastated the JCP
that it had virtually ceased to exist. The party was revived only in the
aftermath of Japan’s defeat in World War II.
Did the American Occupation Carry Out a “Supplementary Bourgeois
Revolution” in Japan?
The JCP used the two-stage schema as part of its justification for
initially supporting the post-WWII Occupation led by American imperialism, which
had indiscriminately firebombed most major cities in Japan and leveled Hiroshima
and Nagasaki with atom bombs. The JCP’s groveling effort to ingratiate itself
with the Allied authorities also represented the continuation of the support
which pro-Moscow parties around the world had given to the so-called
“democratic” imperialist war effort after Germany invaded the USSR in 1941. The
American Communist Party condemned U.S. workers who went on strike during the
war as allies of Hitler and the Mikado (the emperor) and supported the
internment of Japanese Americans. In 1945, the American CP hailed the atom
bombing of Hiroshima and Nagasaki!
The JCP hailed the Occupation authorities for moving against the
so-called “feudalistic elements” of the Japanese ruling elite. In late 1945, a
veteran JCP cadre, Yamamoto Masami, exulted that under the Occupation, “the
military cliques were eliminated, the bureaucratic cliques were finally losing
their relative independence,...the so-called familistic zaibatsu were also
beginning to be dissolved, and even the landownership of parasitic landlords was
being touched” (quoted in Germaine Hoston, Marxism and the Crisis of
Development in Prewar Japan [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986]).
The JCP retained a conciliatory approach to General Douglas MacArthur and his
occupation forces even after the Cold War began in earnest in 1947. The Japanese
Stalinists did not call for an end to the occupation until Moscow publicly
denounced them for not doing so in 1950, and then they did so in the name of
Japanese nationalism. In the 1970s, the JCP broke with both Moscow and Beijing
in favor of overt social democracy.
The view of the American Occupation as some kind of “democratic”
revolution remains the predominant view on the reformist Japanese left. A few
years ago, the journal of the Trotsky Research Institute (TRI) wrote:
“The postwar reforms that were carried out by the American
Occupation army were on the one hand almost thoroughgoing bourgeois reforms in a
country that had a belated industrial structure and a strong state that was
invasion hungry while simultaneously being in revolutionary turmoil. It was a
situation where [in the prewar period] landowners ruled over semi-feudalistic
villages, factory workers received very low wages and there was an absence of
rights. On the other hand, the American Occupation army removed in one breath
the dictatorial emperor system, unleashing a flowering movement from below which
they then had to suppress and force back into the framework of a bourgeois
state. Thus, because the Meiji Restoration was a ‘bureaucratic semi-bourgeois
revolution from above’ which prevented a bourgeois revolution from below, the
postwar reforms carried out by the American Occupation army were a
‘supplementary bourgeois revolution from above’ to prevent a socialist
revolution from below. Thus Japan set a rare precedent against Trotsky’s
prognosis that backward capitalist countries, in order to join the group of
advanced capitalist countries, would have to go through the experience of
permanent revolution.”
— Nishijima Sakae, Torotsukii Kenkyu (Trotsky Studies),
Summer 2001 (our translation)
The Trotsky Research Institute was formed in 1990 primarily by
members of the Japan Revolutionary Communist League (JRCL), part of the
international pseudo-Trotskyist tendency led at the time by Ernest Mandel. The
Mandelites drew into their misnamed anti-Trotskyist endeavor some JCP
intellectuals, like Nishijima Sakae, who wrote the article quoted above.
There was no avowedly Trotskyist group in Japan during Trotsky’s
lifetime. It was only under the impact of the 1956 Hungarian political
revolution that disparate elements from the JCP and independent Marxist
intellectuals leaning toward Trotskyism came together to form the heterogeneous
JRCL in 1957. Emerging in the context of the virulent anti-Sovietism of 1950s
Japan, with no historical link to Trotsky’s International Left Opposition, the
Japanese “Trotskyists” rejected Trotsky’s analysis of the bureaucracy as a
contradictory caste and refused to militarily defend the USSR. Thus, they were
fundamentally crippled from the beginning. Misidentifying Trotskyism as a simple
democratic opposition to Stalinism, the JRCL and their JCP allies in the TRI
joined the virulently anti-Soviet Japanese bourgeoisie in hailing the
destruction of the Soviet Union and the deformed workers states of East
Europe.
Before considering what actually happened in Japan under the U.S.
Occupation regime of General MacArthur, it is first necessary to address a
common confusion at the theoretical level. Liberals and social democrats often
assign the label “bourgeois-democratic revolution” or simply “democratic
revolution” to any political upheaval which results in a change to a
parliamentary system, whether effected by external forces or internally. But the
concept of a bourgeois revolution in an advanced capitalist country is a
contradiction in terms. Thus the uprising led by the Social Democrats in Germany
in November 1918 which overthrew Kaiser Wilhelm II, in the wake of Germany’s
defeat in the First World War, was not a bourgeois-democratic
revolution. It was an incipient proletarian revolution. The
working class not only demanded the overthrow of the Kaiser, but created workers
and soldiers councils—soviets—all over the country. However, the Social
Democratic leadership in bloc with the army high command and right-wing
paramilitary forces bloodily suppressed the organs of proletarian dual power and
exterminated the revolutionary vanguard of the German working class represented
by Rosa Luxemburg and Karl Liebknecht. In the aftermath, a parliamentary
government (the Weimar Republic) was established, which lasted until it was
replaced by the Nazi regime of Adolf Hitler in 1933. The successive governments
of Kaiser Wilhelm II, the Social Democratic leader Friedrich Ebert and the
fascist Adolf Hitler all politically represented the German
financial and industrial bourgeoisie personified by Siemens and Krupp.
In Italy and western Germany as well as Japan, the post-1945
American-led military occupation brought about parliamentary governments. Unlike
the Japanese emperor system, the bourgeois character of the Italian and German
fascist regimes was manifest, certainly to Marxists, even though Italy retained
the monarchy. Mussolini and Hitler originally came to power under conditions of
fragile parliamentarist regimes shaken by massive social turbulence. Decisive
sections of the Italian and German bourgeoisies supported the fascist movement
out of fear of “red revolution.” Thus leading German capitalist magnate Alfred
Hugenberg, a former director of the Krupp empire, played a key role in
installing Hitler as chancellor.
The emperor system of Hirohito was obviously of a different
political character than the fascist regimes of Mussolini and Hitler. Not only
was it derived from the feudal epoch, but Japan had never experienced
parliamentary democracy. Nonetheless, the government of Hirohito and General
Tojo politically represented the dominant sections of Japanese financial and
industrial capital.
Neither the economic dominance nor the composition of the upper
echelon of the Japanese bourgeoisie changed under the American Occupation. U.S.
authorities initially talked about breaking up the zaibatsu, as part of a
plan to wreck any possibility of Japan’s re-emergence as an industrial power. In
the end nothing was actually done in this regard. The conventional
identification today of Japanese capitalism with the names Mitsubishi, Mitsui,
Sumitomo et al. testifies to the continuity of the Japanese ruling
class from the Meiji era through the present.
The U.S. Occupation regime also preserved the continuity of the
Japanese civilian (as distinct from military) political elite. Hirohito remained
emperor, although forced to publicly abjure the claim of divine lineage. Yoshida
Shigeru, the prime minister during most of the Occupation and also the first
post-Occupation years, had been a senior diplomat in pre-1945 imperial Japan,
serving among other posts as ambassador to Britain. The other top Japanese
officials under the Occupation had career résumés similar to, if less exalted
than, Yoshida’s.
Below the level of the top government officials, the civilian state
bureaucracy, including its extensive police apparatus, was preserved intact and
served as the administrative agency which implemented the policies of
MacArthur’s General Headquarters (GHQ). Even members of the notorious Tokko
(Special Security Police), commonly known as the thought-control police, were
simply reassigned to other ministries. No doubt, many of them were instrumental
in carrying out the “red purge” undertaken by the U.S. authorities in the later
years of the Occupation.
In Italy and western Germany, the changes effected during the
American-led occupation were mainly limited to the political superstructure.
There were no substantial changes at the economic base of these societies. In
Japan, however, the U.S. Occupation regime carried out a land reform that
transformed the mass of tenant farmers into small and middling agrarian
proprietors. Announcing this reform in late 1945, MacArthur, a right-wing
American militarist, declared it would “destroy the economic bondage which has
enslaved the Japanese farmer for centuries of feudal oppression” (quoted in R.P.
Dore, Land Reform in Japan [London: Oxford University Press, 1959]).
As we have seen, the main body of Japanese leftists, represented by
the JCP, had long maintained that feudal forms of exploitation continued to
predominate in agriculture. To assess the specific import of MacArthur’s land
reform, it is necessary to consider the overall policies of the American
Occupation regime, especially as they interacted with the escalating Cold War in
East Asia marked by the 1949 Chinese Revolution and the Korean War of
1950-53.
The Labor Upsurge and the U.S. Occupation
The Occupation can be divided into three phases. The first,
“liberal” phase saw a massive upsurge of working-class radicalism. This was
followed by a period, dubbed the “reverse course” by historians, of political
reaction and repression combined with economic austerity. The final period,
precipitated by the outbreak of the Korean War in June 1950, marked the
formation of the alliance between American imperialism and reviving Japanese
imperialism against the Soviet Union and China.
The labor upsurge was sparked in September 1945 by a strike of
Chinese prisoners of war and Korean forced laborers in the mines of Hokkaido.
The Japanese government and mine owners hired thugs to instigate racist attacks,
but their attempts to turn Japanese workers against their Chinese and Korean
class brothers met with defeat. The courageous actions of the Hokkaido miners
sparked a wider strike wave. By December 1946, 92 percent of the miners in Japan
were organized. A year and a half after the war’s end, nearly 4.5 million
workers were enrolled in trade unions, compared to fewer than a half million at
the prewar peak.
The Communist Party was the only major political organization in
imperial Japan that had opposed the imperialist drive toward colonization and
world war. Consequently, its leaders and cadres emerged from prison or returned
from exile with enormous moral authority extending well beyond the party’s
previous base of support. One American liberal historian recounts in his major
study of the Occupation:
“That the most principled resistance to the war had come from
dedicated Communists gave these individuals considerable status. When Tokuda
Kyuichi and several hundred other Communists were released from prison, they
became celebrities and instant heroes in a society whose old heroes had all
suddenly been toppled. Similarly, [JCP leader] Nosaka Sanzo’s arrival in January
1946 after a long journey from China attracted a great crowd. He, too, received
a hero’s welcome; even conservatives, it was said, joined in.”
— John Dower, Embracing Defeat, Japan in the Wake of World War
II (New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1999)
The public meetings which greeted the release of the JCP leaders
attracted large numbers of ethnic Koreans. Korean JCP leader Kim Ch’on-hae
played a central role in organizing the militant Korean organization Chouren; he
toured the country urging Koreans to join Chouren and the JCP. JCP militants won
leadership of the most militant union federation, Sanbetsu. The working class
was clearly on the offensive. The most dramatic and significant aspect of labor
radicalism in this period was the formation of “production control” committees
which took over factories and challenged the traditional authority of management
and ownership. An American left-liberal publicist who visited Japan at the time
wrote:
“In the early days of the occupation most disputes were settled
quickly, and usually with a victory for the union. Employers were stunned by the
defeat, disorganized and uncertain, fearful of antagonizing the occupation
forces, and in some cases, no doubt, apprehensive of revolutionary
developments.”
— Miriam S. Farley, Aspects of Japan’s Labor Problems (New
York: The John Day Company, 1950)
Land Reform and the Defeat of the Postwar Upsurge
The land reform program implemented by MacArthur was explicitly
designed to prevent the rural masses from joining forces with the urban
working-class upsurge. On May Day 1946 three million workers and peasants
participated in nationwide demonstrations. With a growing food crisis, Citizens
Food Control Committees were springing up in various parts of the country. On
May 19, a Food May Day was held in Tokyo with 300,000 workers and poor farmers
surrounding the prime minister’s office and demanding his resignation.
These events frightened the Occupation forces, and in response they
hurried to bring out a land reform program, which was finally announced in
October 1946. A third of all arable land in Japan (just short of two million
cho—almost five million acres) was transferred from landlords to tenant farmers.
Landlords were required to sell this land to the government, which in turn
resold it at the same purchase price to their tenants or other working farmers.
The financial side of this operation was greatly facilitated by the high rate of
inflation at the time. Both the government and the farmers who purchased land
from it were able to pay in rapidly depreciating yen. Most tenants did not need
recourse to long-term loans but were able to buy the land outright for cash in a
year or two.
The proportion of land cultivated under some form of tenancy
arrangement declined from 45 to 10 percent. And the number of purely tenant
farmers (i.e., those who did not own any land) declined from 28 to 5 percent of
all farmers. There was thus a substantial change in the structure of land
ownership and a reduction in the surplus value (rent and interest) extracted
from the rural toilers. This defused unrest in the countryside and allowed
MacArthur to concentrate on defeating the working class in the cities.
Meanwhile, in the cities labor and the Japanese government were
headed toward a major confrontation. The economic situation continued to
disintegrate, with prices of basic necessities increasing nearly four-fold.
Discontent was also fed by the sense that nothing much had changed in the
political structure of the country. Sanbetsu called for a general strike on 1
February 1947, demanding not only higher wages but the ouster of the right-wing,
widely despised Yoshida government, and for the establishment of a “people’s
government,” demands that were enthusiastically supported by all three major
union federations representing some four million workers. But the Japanese
Stalinists, like their counterparts in West Europe, were unwilling and
unprepared to fight for political power. Frightened, but desiring to save face,
they asked MacArthur’s headquarters to issue a written order forbidding the
strike, which MacArthur did. At literally the eleventh hour, Ii Yashiro, head of
the strike committee, called off the strike in a radio announcement.
The JCP handed the working class a huge defeat, negatively shaping
the post-WWII social order. They also lost an enormous opportunity to cut
through the virulent Japanese nationalism which had tied the working class to
its rulers. Chouren had collected money and organized strike support committees,
writing in its newspaper, “The February general strike planned by the Japanese
working class, which is in our mutual interest, should be our struggle. Their
victory will be our victory and their defeat will be our defeat.” Chouren wasn’t
even informed that the strike was called off! The Stalinists soon lost their
positions of strength and authority throughout the country.
The U.S. Occupation regime now moved to break the leftist-led labor
movement. In 1948, MacArthur’s headquarters banned all strikes by government
workers, who had heretofore been in the forefront of labor militancy. This was
followed by a major “red purge.” Some 20,000 Communist Party activists and other
leftists were fired from their jobs. As a result, the membership of Sanbetsu
plummeted from over a million in mid 1949 to less than 300,000 a year later. The
social democratic-led unions, too, lost members in this period.
Japan emerged from the Occupation with the weakest
labor movement of any major advanced capitalist country. In 1953 a strike at
Nissan was defeated. In the aftermath, the private industrial sector workers
were organized into company-financed and -controlled “unions.” In this way it
was the repressive policies of the “reverse course,” not the “progressive”
reforms of the earlier period, which contributed greatly to the Japanese
“economic miracle” of the 1950s-’60s.
Agriculture, the Cold War and the Japanese “Economic Miracle”
The claim that the land reform implemented under the American
Occupation constituted some kind of bourgeois revolution is most often based on
the argument that the pre-1945 agrarian system blocked Japan’s further
modernization. This argument has two components. The first is the belief that
the impoverished condition of the rural toilers limited the domestic market for
industrial products. The second is that the development of a modern agriculture
sector was essential to Japan’s development and that the poverty of the pre-WWII
tenant farmers blocked this development since they lacked both the financial
means and economic incentives to invest in modern technology.
In the historical short term, the increase in disposable income
among farm households as a result of the land reform was spent, predictably,
almost entirely on consumption rather than investment. To a large extent the
increased consumption of former tenant farmers and their families simply
replaced that of their former landlords. In any case, the increased consumer
demand for manufactured goods in the rural villages was at most a minor
contributing factor to Japan’s rapid industrial growth in the 1950s.
The second component of the argument also does not withstand
scrutiny. The leaders of Meiji Japan pursued a policy of agricultural
self-sufficiency for the same reason they effectively barred foreign investment
and built up a modern military-industrial complex: to protect Japan’s
independence against the threat of Western imperialist states. In the 1890s, the
leading Meiji statesman, Tani Kanjo, a onetime minister of agriculture and
commerce, declared that Japan had to be able to feed itself in the event of war,
that self-sufficiency in basic foodstuffs was even more important than
self-sufficiency in modern weaponry.
However, it was inefficient and contrary to the dynamics of the
world capitalist market for Japan to retain a significant agricultural sector.
Thus a major economic motive for Japan’s colonialist expansionism into East
Asia, from the 1890s through the 1930s, was to obtain secure sources of
relatively cheap, basic foodstuffs as well as raw materials for industry. When
in late 1941 Japan went to war with the U.S., 31 percent of its rice and 58
percent of its soybeans came from Manchuria and the other occupied regions of
China, in addition to Japan’s older Asian colonies of Korea and Formosa
(Taiwan).
The most significant effect of the land reform sponsored by the
American Occupation authorities was at the political, rather than economic
level. In the 1920s and early 1930s, tenant farmers and other peasant
smallholders had engaged in mass, organized struggle under the leadership of
Communists and other leftists against the rapacious landlords and village
moneylenders. When in the mid to late 1940s Japanese peasants acquired their own
land along with government-subsidized loans, they became politically
conservative. Rural villages provided a large (though gradually diminishing)
fraction of the votes which have kept the right-wing Liberal Democratic Party
(LDP) in governmental power in Tokyo for all but a brief period in the mid
1990s. The LDP continues to retain a farming sector for political reasons. This
entails not only a high level of protectionism, but also massive economic
subsidies and rural public works programs which are a drain on the overall
economy.
The “red purge” and union-busting offensive initiated in 1947 by
the U.S. Occupation regime initially coincided with and were reinforced by a
program of economic austerity. This was known as the “Dodge line” after its main
architect, a right-wing Detroit banker, Joseph Dodge. Under Dodge’s orders, the
Japanese government slashed expenditures while the supply of money and credit
was sharply contracted. As a consequence 500,000 workers were laid off in both
the government and private sectors. An estimated third of all small businesses
went bankrupt.
Yet two decades later it had become commonplace to speak of a
Japanese “economic miracle.” The root cause of Japan’s dramatic change of
economic fortunes lay in world-historic events on the Asian mainland. When in
1945 the U.S. defeated Japan, the American imperialists believed they had
finally gained control of China, the great prize for which the Pacific War was
mainly fought. U.S. ruling circles looked to Chiang Kai-shek’s regime in Beijing
as their main point of support in East Asia. This was indicated at the
diplomatic level by making China one of five permanent members of the Security
Council of the newly formed United Nations. In line with Washington’s
China-oriented strategy, Japan was to be kept down, prevented from again
becoming a major (and potentially rival) capitalist power in the Far East.
When, however, in 1949 Mao Zedong’s peasant-based People’s
Liberation Army routed Chiang’s forces in the Chinese civil war, American
imperialism’s plans for domination of East Asia were thrown into disarray. The
U.S. rulers moved to build up Japan as their main strategic ally in the region,
a move greatly accelerated by the Korean War. It was this major war between
American imperialism and the Asian Communist countries which finally pulled
Japan out of its prolonged post-1945 economic depression.
Mitsubishi, Toyota et al., became quartermasters for the American
expeditionary forces in Korea, supplying them with a wide array of matériel,
from trucks and ammunition to uniforms and pharmaceuticals. During the first
eight months of the war, steel production increased by almost 40 percent.
Japanese industry was also mobilized to provide repair facilities for U.S. naval
vessels, aircraft and tanks. Prime Minister Yoshida exultantly described the
Korean War as “a gift of the gods.”
Thus began the Japanese “economic miracle” that would last another
two decades. During the 1950s-’60s, Japan consistently ran large balance of
trade surpluses with the U.S. The powers that be on Wall Street and in
Washington accepted this at the time as part of the overhead costs of
maintaining their strategic alliance with Japan against the Sino-Soviet states.
Not until the early 1970s did the U.S. move to stem the flood of Japanese
manufactured imports through various protectionist devices. This marked the
beginning of the end of the Japanese “economic miracle.” In the decade since the
counterrevolutionary destruction of the Soviet Union, Japan has been mired in a
prolonged economic slump.
Forward to a Japanese Workers Republic!
When the JCP—under pressure from Moscow—finally began to oppose the
Occupation, it contended that the Allied troops had turned Japan into a
dependency, even a “semicolony,” of American imperialism. In 1950, JCP Secretary
General Tokuda Kyuichi compared Japan to pre-1949 China under the American
puppet regime of Chiang Kai-shek! Under the pretext that an “anti-imperialist”
revolution is necessary to rid Japan of its dependent status, to this day the
JCP continues to promote the two-stage schema:
“The present state of Japan is marked by its state subordination
to the United States, which is extraordinary not only among the developed
capitalist countries but in international relations of the present-day world, in
which colonization is history. The U.S. domination of Japan clearly has an
imperialistic character because it tramples on Japan’s sovereignty and
independence in the interests of U.S. global strategy and U.S. monopoly
capitalism....
“A change Japanese society needs at present is a democratic
revolution instead of a socialist revolution. It is a revolution that ends
Japan’s extraordinary subordination to the United States and the tyrannical rule
by large corporation and business circles, a revolution that secures Japan’s
genuine independence and carries out democratic changes in politics, the economy
and society.”
— Nihon Kyosan-to Koryo (Japanese Communist Party Program),
adopted at 23rd Congress, January 2004 (JCP draft translation)
A 1956 article in the Rebel, a direct precursor to the
pseudo-Trotskyist JRCL, described Japan in language similar to the Stalinists as
“a special dependency which lies between a colony and a dependency.” This is a
view which pervades the reformist Japanese left. Thus the “New Left” group
Kakumaru, which originated as a virulently Stalinophobic split from the JRCL in
1958, fulminates that:
“The Koizumi regime accepts all political, economic and military
requests demanded by the Bush regime.... While Koizumi may wear a headband with
a hinomaru [rising sun] on it, his underpants are oversized stars and stripes
trunks and his shoes are U.S. military boots.”
—Kaiho (Liberation), 19 January 2004 (our translation)
With its overwhelming military superiority, the U.S. remains the
predominant imperialist power on the face of the planet. But in the face of
growing tensions with the U.S., particularly since the counterrevolutionary
collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991-92, the Japanese bourgeoisie has
dramatically increased its efforts to build up its military to match its
economic power and to demonstrate its determination to protect its own
imperialist interests throughout Asia. Japan dispatched naval vessels, aircraft
and 1,000 military personnel to the Indian Ocean to aid the U.S. invasion of
Afghanistan in 2001. It has a contingent of approximately 500 soldiers
participating in the occupation of Iraq. In portraying Japan as being under the
thumb of American imperialism, the pseudo-socialist left shows itself to be
mired in Japanese nationalism, playing into the hands of the most extreme
revanchist elements of the Japanese bourgeoisie.
At the First Congress of the Toilers of the Far East in
January-February 1922 Zinoviev correctly declared, “The Japanese proletariat
holds in their hands the key to the solution of the Far Eastern question.” While
the proletariat now has real social weight in other Asian countries, the
Japanese working class remains the powerhouse of the region. If Japanese workers
are not to be plunged into mass unemployment or new imperialist adventures, they
must join with the workers of Indonesia, Vietnam, Thailand, China and the Korean
peninsula in the fight for a socialist Asia. In particular, this means rallying
to the military defense of the states where capitalism has been abolished in
Asia—China, North Korea and Vietnam—despite their Stalinist leaderships. A
proletarian revolution in Japan would be a powerful impetus to the Chinese
proletariat to throw out the bureaucrats who are opening the country up to
imperialist exploitation and the threat of internal counterrevolution. But this
means breaking with the virulent nationalism that is the ideological
justification for Japanese imperialism.
In his 1933 article, Trotsky noted that “The hasty mixture of
Edison with Confucius has left its mark on all of Japanese culture.” Japan today
continues to be marked in myriad ways by the feudal past. Article 1 of the
postwar constitution declares that the emperor is “the symbol of the State and
of the unity of the people” and he continues to serve as a powerful rallying
point for all the reactionary forces in Japanese society. All official dates,
both government and commercial, are figured in terms of the year of the current
emperor’s reign. The state continues to base itself on Shinto mythology, with
its racist notion of the superiority of the Yamato peoples. Japanese citizenship
is not automatically granted even to fourth- and fifth-generation Korean and
Chinese born in Japan.
There continues to be discrimination against those whose ancestry
is Burakumin. Because the majority of Burakumin are forced to live in segregated
neighborhoods, the address on the state’s familial registration papers
immediately identifies them. Burakumin children are bullied at school, adults
are denied jobs, and in many cases lovers are separated by reactionary relatives
who still believe the Burakumin are subhuman.
Japan—home to the bullet train, Sony PlayStation, robotics and
developer of state of the art precision technology—has the technological
capability, if placed in the hands of the world’s working class, to tremendously
accelerate the elimination of hunger, want and disease. But women are still
prohibited from entering tunnels under construction for bullet trains out of
fear that the “mountain goddess” will become jealous. Nor can they step inside a
sumo dojo (wrestling ring), because they are “impure.” The Japanese
language continues to have a demeaning four-tiered structure requiring different
levels of submissiveness depending on the class, age, sex and social status of
the person one is addressing. Onna kotoba, a separate spoken language for
women, deliberately promotes obedience and submissiveness and is required for
all public functions and for use inside the family when a woman addresses her
in-laws. The SGJ fights for the elimination of status, age and sex
discrimination, and their concomitant reflection in demeaning language.
In almost all social indices Japanese women place at the bottom of
the advanced industrial countries. Just over half of Japanese women work,
compared with 70 percent of their Western counterparts. The “good wife, wise
mother” ideology is codified in law and corporate practices. Most companies
provide male workers with family allowances if the wife does not work; these
allowances are often more than a married woman working part-time could make.
Seventy-seven percent of all part-time workers in Japan are female. On average,
women’s salaries are just 60 percent of men’s, and this percentage has remained
steady since women first entered the workforce as textile workers in the late
1800s. The social pressure exerted on a woman who hits 30 to marry and assume
her “appropriate place” in society is immense. Older unmarried women are
referred to as makeinu (losing dogs) and motenai onna (unwanted
females).
The International Communist League stands on the heritage of
Trotsky’s Fourth International, studying with a critical eye its programmatic
and political decisions in order to arm ourselves for future battles. Similarly,
a critical approach to our legacy from the first four congresses of the
Communist International has led us to have left reservations about some of the
decisions made at and around the Fourth Congress. The Spartacist Group Japan
continues the fight to forge an authentically communist party in Japan. This
party can only be built on the basis of uncompromising struggle against
recrudescent Japanese chauvinism, resurgent militarism, and the horrible
oppression of women. The Sasebo dock workers who refused to load military goods
onto Japanese military ships bound for the Indian Ocean in 2001 provided a
powerful example to the proletariat internationally. Abolish the emperor system!
Japanese troops out of Iraq, the Indian Ocean, East Timor and the Golan Heights!
For an end to the discrimination against the Burakumin and Ainu! Throw the
family registry into the trash bin! For full citizenship for ethnic Koreans and
Chinese and all who live in Japan! Tear up the gaijin (foreigner) cards!
Equal pay for equal work! For free, safe birth control and free, 24-hour
childcare and nursing care for the elderly! The Spartacist Group Japan champions
demands such as these as part of its overall program for socialist revolution.
It is only on this program that the revolutionary proletarian party which can
lead the fight to overthrow capitalism in Japan can be forged. Forward to a
Japanese workers republic!
Endnote
A selection of documents from the Comintern archives on the JCP has
been published in Russian in VKP(b), Komintern i Yaponiya 1917-1941
(The VKP(b) [All-Union Communist Party (bolshevik)], the Comintern and Japan,
1917-1941 [Moscow: Russian Political Encyclopedia, 2001]), which we
consulted for this article. In 1998 and 1999, Professor Kato Tetsuro, a
social-democratic, anti-Communist historian, published the results of his
research into the JCP Comintern archives in Japanese in a series of articles,
“1922.9 no Nihon Kyosan-to Koryo” [ue, shita]; “Dai Ichi-ji Kyosan-to no
Mosukuwa Hokoku Sho” [ue, shita] (Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyujo Zasshi,
Hosei Daigaku, Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyujo, 1998.12, 1999.1, 1999.8, 1999.11)
(“1922 Program of the Japanese Communist Party” [Parts I and II] and “Moscow
Report of the First Communist Party” [Parts I and II], Ohara Institute for
Social Research Journal, December 1998, January, August, November 1999). The
comprehensive collection of microfilmed documents, Comintern Archives: Files
of the Communist Party of Japan, published in the spring of 2004 by IDC
publishers in the Netherlands, was unfortunately not yet available for the
preparation of this article.
Manifesto
by the Preparatory Committee for the Japanese Communist Party
April 1921
by the Preparatory Committee for the Japanese Communist Party
April 1921
This document was written in English by Yamakawa Hitoshi and
sent to representatives of the Communist International in Shanghai for
transmission to Moscow. Unfortunately, the original English version could not be
located in the Comintern Archives in the Russian State Archive of
Socio-Political History in Moscow. We translated this from the Russian
version—first published in The Peoples of the Far East (No. 4, 1921)—as
it appears in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan. The process of
retranslation, while unavoidable, has no doubt introduced drift and perhaps
inaccuracies.
At the time this manifesto was written, the Soviet Red Army was
conducting mopping-up operations in the wake of its victory over imperialist
interventionist forces and the counterrevolutionary White armies operating under
their patronage. Anton Deniken, Peter Wrangel, Alexander Kolchak and G.
Semenov—all former tsarist officers—were military commanders of the White
forces. Alexander Kerensky was head of the bourgeois Provisional Government that
had been overthrown by the Bolsheviks in October 1917. In the summer of 1918
Japanese imperialist forces invaded the Russian Far East, where they worked in
league with Semenov; Japanese troops did not leave Vladivostok until November
1922.
Seiyukai (Association of Political Friends) was the dominant
bourgeois party in Japan at the time. It was founded in 1900 after the
decomposition of Jiyuto (Liberal Party), and evolved into a diehard conservative
party. In 1900, Hara Takashi (also known as Hara Kei) joined Seiyukai and became
its secretary general, running the party with several others through 1914. The
so-called “People’s Cabinet” (Heimin Naikaku) refers to the cabinet in which
Hara was prime minister, formed after the 1918 Rice Riots. Because Hara was
neither a member of the peerage nor from any of the four domains (i.e., Satsuma,
Choshu, Tosa or Hizen) that had dominated the government from 1868, he has been
called the “commoner” prime minister. Hara’s popularity declined due to his
relentless opposition to universal suffrage and he was assassinated in November
1921.
A spectre is haunting Europe, said Karl Marx at one time. Today,
after 75 years, this spectre is haunting not only Europe, but the whole world.
The powers of the whole world have united in one holy alliance to drive away the
spectre of communism. The League of Nations, the League of Denikins, Wrangels
and Kerenskys with French and British imperialists; the union of Kolchaks with
Semenovs and Japanese militarists, just as thousands of other leagues and
alliances, all bear witness to the fact that capitalism is placing its final
decisive stake in its struggle for its existence.
The Revolution of 1867 was the victory of mercantile capital over
feudalism. Capitalist relations had not sufficiently matured up to that point in
time, however, and could not, for this reason, also correspondingly reconstruct
the political system. Power went to the lower layers of the old privileged
classes, instead of passing directly to the bourgeoisie. This circumstance
became the reason for the rise of a most complex bureaucratic apparatus and
despotic monarchy in Japan—instead of bourgeois republicanism.
Industrial capitalism continued to develop from this point on in
Japan under the paternal wing of the bureaucracy. The bureaucracy from its own
side clearly took into account the fact that it could not survive without
collaboration with the capitalists. Thus the past 50 years (from the moment of
the 1867 Revolution) is the history of the development of capitalism under the
sluggish and clumsy bureaucracy.
The Sino-Japanese and Russo-Japanese wars were decisive for the
history of capitalism in Japan. We all remember how Japanese capitalism bloated,
gorging on the suffering and blood of not only its own people, but of the
proletariat of neighboring countries. On this basis militarism and imperialism
with such determination sank deep roots into the sun-drenched islands of the Far
East.
The four years of the great European war afforded enough time and
opportunity for Japanese capitalism to enter the world arena fully armed.
The development of capitalism prior to its present state naturally
found its reflection in the political situation of the country, as the so-called
“People’s Cabinet” (Heimin Naikaku)—a government composed exclusively of
representatives of the parties of large landlords and capitalists,
“Seiyukai”—reached a dominant position, monopolizing parliament, the
municipalities, stock market and banks. The hour had finally arrived, when the
bourgeoisie of Japan could come out independently, no longer hiding behind or
seeking the protection of the monarchical bureaucracy. From this moment of the
bourgeoisie’s open entry into the arena, the proletariat of Japan understood
what its own position was in society.
In this way, the progress of capitalism in Japan, true as ever to
its historic mission, gave impetus to the proletarian movement. The sharp growth
of the workers movement in 1918 and later on, the innumerable strikes and
workers protests, the rapid awakening and development of class consciousness of
the workers, the powerful, unstoppable spread of socialist doctrine throughout
the country—all of this is the fruit of the economic development of Japan.
This development is typical not only for the cities and suburbs.
The rural population has been drawn in as well. The rapid capitalization of
land, the swallowing of small farms by large landlords have had the result of
placing 60 percent of the population in the ranks of the proletariat. And today
there is no doubt that a significant majority of the rural population will
consciously go shoulder to shoulder with the urban proletariat in the coming
battle for liberation. The decisive class differentiation between the
proletariat and bourgeoisie in Japan—this is an already accomplished fact, and
both classes are carrying on an intense struggle with each other. The “Rice
Riots” that swept the country in the summer of 1918 and that within two weeks
made the government tremble in their boots fired the revolutionary spirit of the
broad masses. This was an indication that the moment of decisive struggle for
the overthrow of capitalism has arrived.
Alongside the proletarian movement, the influence of socialism has
grown in Japan as well. For an entire quarter of a century Japanese socialists
courageously, but unsuccessfully fought with those mighty forces that were
organized by the gigantic police apparatus of the militarist bureaucracy. But
the time has finally arrived when we may reward ourselves for all the past
sacrifices. We now have a truly revolutionary proletariat; the broad popular
masses are seized by a spirit of indignation; we have in addition the Communist
Party of Japan, the vanguard of the proletarian revolutionary army.
Further, at the same time as capitalist Japan has entered the arena
of international capitalist exploitation, the Japanese proletariat has entered
onto the broad road of World Revolution. When the proletariat of Russia
overthrew its oppressors in the momentous October days, the left wing of
Japanese socialists, in spite of vigilance of the police and spy networks,
joyfully hailed the brilliant victory of their Russian comrades. We stated then,
“The proletariat of each country must eliminate the bayonets aimed against the
workers of other countries, and aim them against their genuine enemies in their
own countries.”
We were too weak then to carry out our words in deeds, but we still
firmly held the banner of international solidarity of the proletariat even in
the period of vicious incessant attacks by the rabid capitalist government. Now
we are able to greet the revolutionary proletariat of all countries in the name
of the Communist Party of Japan.
Long Live the Proletarian Revolution!
Long Live the Communist International!
Long Live Communism!
Program of the Communist Party of Japan
September 1922
September 1922
This program was written in English in September 1922 and sent
to Moscow for the Fourth Congress of the Communist International, which was held
in November-December 1922. We publish here the original English version found in
the Archives of the Communist International in the Russian State Archive of
Socio-Political History in Moscow. We have added obvious dropped words,
corrected obvious misspellings and use of definite articles and prepositions,
but otherwise not changed the somewhat awkward English.
The document was sent to the Comintern over the signatures of
Aoki Kunekichi (pseudonym of Arahata Kanson), as General Secretary of the JCP,
and Sakatani Goro (pseudonym of Sakai Toshihiko), as the party’s International
Secretary. They wrote that the program was approved by a national convention of
the JCP held in September 1922, but we have found no other record that a JCP
conference was held at that time.
The last section of the program opposes Japanese imperialist
expansion in Asia. When the program was written, Japan still maintained troops
in the Russian Far East, which it had invaded during the Russian Civil War.
Japan had fought a war against China in 1894-95, winning Formosa (Taiwan) and
economic control of Korea. In 1904-05, Japan fought tsarist Russia, seizing
strategic Port Arthur in southern Manchuria and Southern Sakhalin Island. In
November 1905 Japan declared Korea its protectorate, and in August 1910 annexed
it outright.
The Communist Party of Japan, a section of the Third Communist
International, is an illegal, proletarian political party, whose aim is the
overthrow of the Capitalist regime through the establishment of the Dictatorship
of the Proletariat based on the Soviet Power.
Japan has been the most powerful of the capitalist nations of the
Orient, and the favourable position she occupied during the World War has
brought about a sudden development and expansion of her capitalistic system.
Under the pressure of the world economic crisis, Japanese Capitalism is
struggling hard to tighten its grip of already unequalled exploitation and
persecution upon the toiling masses, the workers, peasants, and other lower
strata of the population. The Communist Party takes upon itself the task of
organizing these proletarian masses into a powerful fighting body, leading them
on to the Proletarian Revolution—the seizure of political power and system of
production in the hands of the proletariat.
Labour Movement
The workers’ movement in Japan is still in an infantile stage. The
trade union movement, under the yoke of the Japanese Tsardom, has not yet
followed the normal line of development. Side by side with a large number of
passive, intimidated, unorganized masses stands a minority of self-conscious,
militant elements, whose temper and ideology are as revolutionary as those of
the most advanced section of the European workers. Even among the unorganized,
the feeling of instinctive revolt is as wide-spread and deep-rooted as among any
brutally oppressed toilers. To these instinctive revolt and revolutionary
demands the Communist Party strives to give a most clearly defined aim as well
as the most effective methods of realizing it. For this purpose, the Communists
must penetrate into every workers’ organization so as to take control of the
union policies, maintain the closest contact with the unorganized masses so as
to educate, guide and organize them for the proletarian struggle. In this
difficult work, the Party, while holding fast the ultimate aim of establishing
the proletarian dictatorship, must organize its legal activities with the view
to an active participation in the daily struggles of the workers, pushing
through at every opportunity the Communist tactics of the “United Front.” Only
through its successful struggle along these lines can the Communist Party expect
to acquire the character of a proletarian mass party, the true vanguard of the
Proletariat.
Some of the more active, influential sections of the industrial
workers have been infected with the infantile malady of the anarcho-syndicalist
ideology. Naively cherishing an illusory idea of the “Free Workers’ Regime,”
they are opposed to centralized organization and all “political” actions
including the establishment of the Dictatorship of the Proletariat, and are
still in a position to lead and influence a minority of workers, to the
detriment of both the immediate need for undivided effort and the ultimate
victory of the proletariat.
These revolutionary elements, while deserving no concession on the
matters of our principles, must be approached by the party with utmost patience
and generosity in order to win as many of them as possible over to our aims and
tactics.
Agrarian Problems
In the domain of agriculture the process of pauperization has been
steadily going on, resulting in a remarkable growth of tenancy and concentration
of land. This tendency was accelerated by the sudden development and expansion
of industries. Awakened by the rebellious action of the industrial workers, the
rural toilers have started to organize and to fight their class enemy, and found
their position strengthened by an acute labour shortage caused by the War. Even
after the industrial depression has set in, the tenant farmers carry on their
fight and organization. They demand a reduction of rent with the threat of
quitting the cultivation; thousands of acres of land have been abandoned by the
tenants; and the owners are being compelled to till it themselves with aid of
hired labour and agricultural machinery.
In view of the situation, and particularly of the more fundamental
fact that the small farmers and the tenants occupy nearly seventy per cent of
the entire population, and without their aid the proletarian victory is
impossible, the Communist Party of Japan should take initiative in the
organization of tenants, carry on an untiring agitation and propaganda in the
villages so that the rural workers may come to understand Communist ideas and
see their only salvation in the Social Revolution.
Political Action
The political parties in this country are the parties of the
Capitalist Class. Their rule, however, is checked by the influence of the
Bureaucrats and Militarist Clique, the remnants of Feudal Japan. Thus, the
conflicts and compromises of the two forces constitute the bone of the present
day politics. Bourgeois Democracy has yet to see its palmiest [most flourishing]
day, and universal suffrage has yet to be fought for.
The Communist Party, while convinced fully of the truth that the
Parliamentary System as such is nothing but a bourgeois institution and in no
way dependable as an instrument of proletarian revolution, nevertheless holds
that its perfection constitutes an essential stage in the normal development of
proletarian struggle. The party, therefore, organizes proletarian political
action to help accelerate the “progress of Democracy.” Our political activities
within and without the parliament, however, must remain a feature of our general
Communist propaganda and agitation. They shall consist in broadening and
intensifying the proletarian struggle on the one hand, and in exposing the
hypocrisy and futility of bourgeois democracy, and demonstrating to the
proletariat the necessity of creating their own machinery of Government on the
other hand. Only thus, the Party believes, will the proletariat be convinced of
the essentially political nature of their struggle and become ready to carry
their fight to the finish, the seizure of political power. And only thus, we are
confident, will the proletariat follow the lead of our party whose goal it is to
establish the Proletarian Dictatorship based on the Soviet of the workers,
peasants and soldiers.
Militarism
The Japanese Empire, known as the Germany of the Orient, has its
world-famous Militarist Bureaucracy. The Jingoes of Japan do not shrink from the
idea of a war with the United States. And their natural allies are the bourgeois
capitalists, whose greed for markets is insatiable.
The secret of the militarist influence lies in their patriotism.
The patriotism which they have been so eager to preach in the schools and armies
still has its hold upon a large mass of people. Blinded and deafened by the
poison of patriotism, they are not yet able to realize that the real function of
the army is to maintain capitalist rule, enabling the capitalists to exploit and
oppress the producing masses ever and ever more effectively.
The Communist Party is determined to fight militarism. By breaking
the spell of patriotism, it must upset the foundation of militarist power, and
thus prepare the way to the organization of the Red army of the revolutionary
proletariat.
Korean, Chinese, and Siberian Questions
The Communist Party of Japan is resolutely opposed to every species
of the Imperialist policy. It is opposed to the intervention, open and secret,
in China and Siberia, the interference with the government of these countries,
the “Sphere of Influence” and “Vested Interests” in China, Manchuria, and
Mongolia, and all the other attempts and practices of similar nature.
The most infamous of all the crimes of Japanese Imperialism has
been the annexation of Korea and the enslavement of the Korean people. The
Communist Party of Japan not only condemns the act but takes every available
step for the emancipation of Korea. The majority of the Korean patriots,
fighting for the Independence of Korea, is not free from bourgeois ideology and
nationalist prejudice. It is necessary that we act in cooperation with
them—necessary not only for the victory of the Korean Revolution but also for
winning them over to our Communist principles. The Korean Revolution will bring
with it a national crisis in Japan, and the fate of both the Korean and Japanese
proletariat will depend on the success or failure of the fight carried on by the
united effort of the Communist Parties of the two countries.
The three principal nations in the Far East, China, Korea, and
Japan, are most closely related to one another in their political, social, and
economic life, and thus bound to march together on to the goal of Communism. The
international solidarity of the proletariat, and particularly of these three
countries is the condition indispensable to the Victory and Emancipation of the
Proletariat, not only of the respective countries but of the whole world.
Report on Differences at the Special Congress of the Japanese
Communist Party
by Arahata Kanson
May 1923
by Arahata Kanson
May 1923
This report on the 15 March 1923 JCP Congress was written in
Japanese in Moscow for the Third Plenum of the Executive Committee of the
Communist International, which was held in June 1923. Unfortunately, the
Japanese original could not be located in the Comintern Archives in the Russian
State Archive of Socio-Political History in Moscow. We have translated this from
the Russian version which appeared in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan.
This Russian text was translated from an English version which was made from
the original Japanese by the Comintern. The process of translation from Japanese
to English to Russian and back has no doubt introduced drift and perhaps
inaccuracies.
Written using Arahata’s pseudonym of Aoki, this report sought to
amplify a report that Sakai, as International Secretary of the JCP, had sent to
the Comintern in March 1923. Sakai’s report detailed the differences that
developed in the JCP over Bukharin’s 1922 draft JCP program and the “two stage”
conception of revolution it propounded. The language in Sakai’s report, written
under the name Sakatani Goro, is not as clear as that used by Arahata. In
several places in this document, Arahata explains phrases used in Sakai’s
report, which is also published in Russian in The VKP(b), the Comintern and
Japan.
Arahata refers to a Mercantile Industrial Party led by Japanese
textile manufacturer Muto Sanji. Muto’s short-lived, liberal bourgeois party is
better known as Jitsugyo Doshikai (Businessmen’s Association).
Yuaikai (Friendly Society) was Japan’s first major labor
organization, founded in 1912 by the Christian reformer Suzuki Bunji. Kagawa
Toyohiko was also a Christian reformer and Yuaikai leader. Modeled on British
friendly (mutual aid) societies, Yuaikai advocated collaboration between labor
and capital, and concentrated on organizing craft unions. In 1919 Yuaikai was
reorganized more along the lines of an industrial union federation and renamed
Dai Nihon Rodo Sodomei-Yuaikai (Greater Japan General Federation of
Labor-Friendly Societies). The name was later shortened to Nihon Rodo Sodomei
(Japan General Federation of Labor), or simply Sodomei.
The Kakushin Kurabu (Reform Club) was a small party that
represented the most liberal members of the Diet, having as its base of support
the urban middle class and prosperous farmers. It advocated universal suffrage
and a reduced military. Its ranks were divided over passage of the Peace
Preservation Law of 1925, and the Reform Club was dissolved that same year, with
most members joining the dominant bourgeois party, Seiyukai.
When Arahata’s report was written the Communist International
was engaged in an international campaign against the French occupation of the
Ruhr, which began in January 1923, after Germany defaulted on the reparations
payments it was forced to pay France under the terms of the Versailles
Treaty.
Certain points of the CC Report are insufficiently clear and
require explanation.
The question of organizing a legal labor party brought out
differences at our Congress. One part of the party insisted on an immediate
founding of a legal political party, another part maintains that the moment for
this has not yet arrived. The first tendency maintains that a bourgeois
revolution in Japan is inevitable and believes that a proletarian revolution is
only possible after a bourgeois [revolution].
They point to the movement for the founding of the Shoko-to
(Mercantile Industrial Party), led by Japanese cotton king Muto Sanji, to the
efforts toward a political workers party led by the chairman of the “Yuaikai”
(Japanese Federation of Labor), Suzuki Bunji, and to an analogous tendency in
the “Kakushin Kurabu,” as symptoms of the coming bourgeois revolution.
If there is not an active Communist Party that will take the
leadership of the movement into its hands, the proletariat will fall under the
influence of the bourgeoisie. It is for this reason that they insist on a legal
political workers-peasants party, which must act to hasten the bourgeois
revolution, which sooner or later must come about. This in turn would prepare
the groundwork for the proletarian revolution that will follow after the
bourgeois revolution. This political party must also include radical elements of
the bourgeoisie, since at the present time the proletariat as a whole still
remains under their influence and it would be difficult to ignore them.
The other part of the Congress supports the position that a purely
bourgeois revolution, along the lines of the Great French Revolution or the
March Revolution in Russia, is impossible in Japan as a result of the rapid
development of the Japanese bourgeoisie during the imperialist war, and even
before that.
In its developing stage, the Japanese bourgeoisie leaned on the
bureaucracy, on the remnants of feudalism. But now it is already able to stand
on its own two feet. In addition to which, the bureaucracy has become an
obstacle to the further development of the bourgeoisie.
After the heavy blow that it took from the economic crisis that
followed the war, the bourgeoisie came to the conclusion that the only course
toward re-establishing its forces was the capture of economic and political
power, tearing the latter out of the hands of the bureaucracy.
It is without a doubt that toward the bureaucracy the Japanese
bourgeoisie is quite radical, but as soon as the question touches on the
overthrow of the Mikado and the establishment of a genuine bourgeois democracy
with republican forms of rule, it becomes thoroughly conservative. Thanks to the
living example of Europe, the bourgeoisie understands full well that the
beginning of any revolution will be its death knell. Just as the Mikado, in the
hands of the bureaucracy, had been a tool for the enslavement of the popular
masses, precisely so is the bourgeoisie using him as a tool for the defense of
their interests. The bourgeoisie fully takes into account the attitude of the
Japanese people toward the Mikado. Even though on the one hand the Mikado
represents an obstacle to the bourgeoisie, in other respects he represents a
valuable tool in their hands. In reality, the bourgeoisie only wishes to replace
the present bureaucratic government. But it maintains that this must be done by
completely constitutional means.
It is absolutely clear that, being unable to independently take
power out of the hands of the bureaucracy, the bourgeoisie must enlist the
popular masses to its side. It is exclusively for this reason that Muto has
launched a movement for the aforementioned (Mercantile Industrial Party), whose
central demand is universal suffrage.
For the same reason, Suzuki and the lackeys of the “Kakushin
Kurabu” strive to form a labor party on this same platform of universal
suffrage.
In this context, the basic question is what tactic should be used
against them. We must very carefully monitor every attempt of theirs to win
support from the masses. For the bourgeoisie to corrupt the masses is an
everyday affair in all capitalist states. If we succeed in winning broad support
of the masses and to lead them, then the hour of proletarian revolution has
arrived. We must remain alert, but our vigilance must not lead us to prematurely
form a political party that would include the most heterogeneous elements. This
would be a tactical mistake.
From this standpoint, it follows that the coming revolution in
Japan will be a proletarian revolution, since, as set out above, the bourgeoisie
is extremely conservative on the question of the overthrow of the Mikado. A
revolution like the Great French Revolution, or the March Revolution in Russia
is unthinkable in Japan as long as the masses are not revolutionized; but when
the masses do become revolutionized, then that is when the hour of the
proletarian revolution will strike.
If we help the bourgeoisie in its strivings to seize power, are we
not consolidating the foundations of bourgeois democracy, and are we not thereby
holding back the development of the proletarian revolution? It is without a
doubt so. That is why we must carry out a policy toward proletarian revolution,
and concentrate all of our attention on this goal. (In the Report, the phrase
“striving to the extent we can, to block the political revolution” should be
understood in the sense of “conduct a policy and develop a movement that will
block the consolidation of bourgeois power.”)
It is from this standpoint that there is opposition to the
formation of a political party in which the worker-communists are to form a left
wing, the social democrats the center, and the radical bourgeoisie, the right
wing.
As to the question of founding a purely proletarian political
party, the first part of the Congress maintained that this must be organized
immediately. They believe that the danger of losing the sympathy of radical
(syndicalist) workers by doing this is only a passing danger. The opposition of
syndicalists to a political movement is actually prompted by the propaganda of
revolutionary socialists in the past. Propaganda for a revolutionary political
movement that we propose will without a doubt prove successful among them. On
the other hand, they argue, if we don’t form such a party, the Labor Party that
Suzuki and the lackeys of Kakushin Kurabu are striving to form will attract many
moderate workers.
In counterposition to these views, the second part of the Congress
declared that irrespective of whether we form a political party or not, it is
absolutely inevitable that many workers will be drawn to the envisioned
reformist Labor Party, and will wind up under its influence. This pertains as
well, and even more so, to the peasantry, a large part of which consists, after
all, of peasant landholders.
For instance, on the question of nationalization of land, the
peasantry will support the program of nationalization with
compensation, that is, the program that a radical bourgeois party is
ready to adopt, but that stands in contradiction to the program of
nationalization without compensation, the program put forward by
the proletarian party. At the present moment the rural population is of course
more backward in its political consciousness than the urban workers. In fact, we
face an interesting paradox—the left wing of the urban working class is inclined
against the founding of a political party, believing that such a party would be
limited in its work exclusively to parliamentarism, while the best
and most radical elements of the rural population support a
political movement, proceeding from these very same
assumptions.
The organized and class-conscious part of the peasants who rent and
of rural proletarians represents just as small a portion of their class as the
organized workers represent of theirs. And nonetheless, Suzuki and Kagawa
Toyohiko, the reformist union leaders, who are gradually losing their influence
among urban workers, preserve their influence among rural workers. In general,
the majority of the working masses in the city, as well as in the village, are
moderate, conservative, and even reactionary and for this reason may become
easily ensnared by bourgeois influences.
For this reason our goal must be the winning of not the broad
masses in general, but the winning of the radical, class-conscious part of the
working class. But the radical elements of the working class are at the present
hostile to political activity, while those elements who are not
hostile are the indifferent ones. For example: Suzuki Bunji preaches that the
class struggle can be ameliorated through universal suffrage, and has publicly
declared that if his Labor Party manages to get into parliament the antagonism
between labor and capital will be eased. Yuaikai, of which Suzuki is the
chairman, at its congress last October adopted a resolution
against universal suffrage and declared that if Suzuki joins the
political movement, he will be expelled from the General Confederation of Labor
(Sodomei). That is the situation in the Sodomei, which has more Communist
elements in its ranks than any other labor organization. Of course this
situation was created as a result of an overly narrow interpretation of
political activity. The left wing cannot free itself of its syndicalist
prejudices, and sees all political activity only as parliamentarism.
Nonetheless, those workers who are inclined against a political
movement represent the very best and the most promising elements of the working
class. Isn’t it true that in the majority of cases those who today join in the
political movement are cheap politicians? Aren’t they simply paid agents of the
Kenseikai party, or people bought with money thrown around by the lackeys of the
Kakushin Kurabu? In spite of their traditional disorientation, we must not leave
the best elements of the working class, and we must ourselves see to it that
they do not turn from us. Being the vanguard of the broad masses, they will in
the near future join us under the banner of Communism and will become true
fighters in the front ranks of revolutionary battles. That is why we must teach
them about politics through practical political activity that creates political
discipline on their part, dispel their prejudices against political work, make a
clear and unbroken connection between economic and political questions, and
teach them that in order to attain the economic liberation of the working class,
the proletariat must first of all seize political power.
The Central Executive Committee of the Japanese Communist Party has
resolved to broaden its activity in economic questions. This plan entails the
strengthening of trade unions, the improvement of the workers movement’s
situation, the winning of workers to the party and the reinforcement of the
economic and political sections of the party. Already in the spring of the
previous year the party organized the “Hands Off Soviet Russia!” movement, it
conducted a campaign opposing legislation against thought crimes, it is
campaigning against the occupation of the Ruhr, and is at the present organizing
a movement of the unemployed. Even though these campaigns have had only partial
success, the party has managed to organize a trade-union committee as the
leading body of these movements. In the end, this practical work (in the report
the term that is used is “direct political action”) cannot but help to raise the
class consciousness of the working masses. At first glance this method of work
may seem protracted, but it will lead to great results in the future. Rather, it
is the premature creation of a political party that will risk us our influence
over radical trade unions. These are the important organizations of the
proletariat, who are in principle hostile to the so-called political movement.
In a country like Japan, where the Communist Party is still young and weak, this
represents a very serious danger.
And so, opinions at the Party Congress divided into two: one part
maintains that a bourgeois revolution is inevitable, while the other part does
not. This naturally will lead to differences over tactical questions in the
future. The Congress concluded, leaving these problems unresolved, tabling them
to the party’s sections, departments, and cells for further detailed
discussion.
In essence, there are actually no disagreements over the founding
of a political party; opinions diverge only over whether this party should take
into its ranks only purely proletarian elements, or others as well, and opinions
diverge over whether such a party should be formed immediately, or do we need to
go more slowly with this.
Spartacist English edition No. 58
|
Spring 2004
|
The Origins of Japanese Communism, Debate over “Two-Stage
Revolution” and the American Occupation
The Meiji Restoration: A Bourgeois Non-Democratic Revolution
Appendix: Historical Documents
This article follows the standard Japanese practice of listing
family names before given names. With the exception of the Japanese Communist
Party, which is always given in English, the names of Japanese institutions and
organizations are rendered in romaji transliterations. The first time a
transliterated name appears, the English translation is given in
parentheses.
Today, Germany and Japan are second only to the United States as
the major capitalist-imperialist powers in the world. In the mid 19th century,
both these countries underwent “revolutions from above” which removed the feudal
(in Japan) and feudal-derived (in Germany) obstacles to their subsequent
development as modern capitalist societies and states. In Germany, Prussian
chancellor Otto von Bismarck waged a series of wars from 1864-71, unifying the
country under the Hohenzollern monarchy and modernizing the state structure.
Bismarck’s actions greatly strengthened an already economically ascendant
industrial, financial and commercial bourgeoisie. In Japan, a section of the old
warrior caste, wielding the image of the Emperor Meiji, ousted the feudal regime
in 1867-68 to build up the Japanese military and enable it to stand up to the
encroachments of the Western powers. In the following decades, they created a
Japanese industrial bourgeoisie. By the beginning of the 20th century, Germany
had become the strongest industrial capitalist state in Europe, Japan the only
industrial capitalist state in Asia.
Both Western and Japanese academics have long recognized the
substantial similarity of the course of development of Germany and Japan.
However, when the Japanese Communist Party (JCP) was founded in 1922, Japan was
much more backward in all major respects—social, economic and political—than
Germany; not only the Germany of the interwar Weimar Republic but also the
pre-1918 Germany of the Hohenzollern monarchy. The emperor ruled not merely “by
the grace of god” but as the descendant of the sun goddess, the mythical founder
of the Japanese nation. Half the Japanese labor force was still engaged in
agriculture, for the most part utilizing pre-industrial technology.
While the leaders of the early Communist International (CI, or
Comintern) sometimes referred to Japan as the “Prussia of the East,” there was
no unanimity on the nature of Japan as an advanced, industrial society
qualitatively similar to Germany. The main CI leader assigned to help the
Japanese party, Nikolai Bukharin, insisted that Japan remained “semi-feudal.”
Beginning in the fall of 1922, the CI sought to impose on the JCP cadre
Bukharin’s analysis of Japan, and with it the two-stage schema of revolution
which the CI was then imposing on all the young Communist parties of the East.
The JCP was instructed to fight for a bourgeois-democratic revolution in which
the Communist Party would join with the liberal bourgeoisie and the peasants in
overthrowing the monarchy; it was only with the completion of the
bourgeois-democratic stage that the Communist Party was to begin the fight for
socialism. Moreover, those in the CI leadership responsible for the JCP failed
to straightforwardly apply the lessons of Bolshevik organization under tsarist
repression—the need for a stable émigré leadership center and network of
couriers to maintain contact with and provide propaganda for underground party
cells in Japan. Thus the JCP was set up to be destroyed by the severe state
repression.
Under the impact of the burgeoning bureaucratic degeneration of the
Soviet state and party, the Communist International in the fall of 1922 was
showing the first signs of abandoning its internationalist purpose (see
“Rearming Bolshevism: A Trotskyist Critique of Germany 1923 and the Comintern,”
Spartacist No. 56, Spring 2001). The isolation of the Soviet Union and
the extreme backwardness of the old tsarist empire—made worse by the destruction
wrought by World War I and the Civil War of 1918-20—led to the development of a
bureaucratic caste within the world’s first workers state. This bureaucracy
usurped political power from the proletariat at the Thirteenth Party Conference
in January 1924 and toward the end of that year Stalin propounded the dogma of
building “socialism in one country,” the theoretical rationale for this
conservative, nationalist layer.
Over the next decade the zigzags and increasing class
collaborationism of the Comintern’s policies, first under Zinoviev and then
under Bukharin and Stalin, led to disaster after disaster as the Communist
parties were gradually transformed into border guards for the Soviet Union and
instruments of its foreign policy. Trotsky fought the CI’s growing misleadership
of revolutionary struggles. Standing on the political heritage of the
Comintern’s first four congresses, he built the Left Opposition in battle
against the CI’s abandonment of a revolutionary perspective, especially in
China. There the program of “two-stage revolution” provided the cover for the
subordination of the interests of the Chinese proletariat to those of Chiang
Kai-shek’s Guomindang (with which the Soviet Union was seeking an alliance
against British imperialism). The result was the strangling of a nascent
proletarian revolution in 1925-27: the “first stage” was the Chinese Communists’
political liquidation into the bourgeois-nationalist forces, the “second stage”
was the physical extermination of the Communists and advanced workers at the
hands of these same bourgeois forces, most notably in the Shanghai massacre of
April 1927.
Forcibly exiled from the Soviet Union in 1929, over the next decade
Trotsky built a movement which resulted in the founding of a new communist
international, the Fourth International, in 1938. The Comintern’s degeneration
culminated in the adoption of an explicit program of class collaboration (the
“popular front”) at the Seventh CI Congress in 1935. In 1943, Stalin dissolved
the Comintern in the interests of his World War II alliance with British,
American and French imperialism.
Trotsky did not write specifically about Japan until the 1930s, and
then only infrequently and mainly in articles about the military situation in
the Pacific leading into WWII. By this time the JCP had been crushed by state
repression. In a 1933 article Trotsky commented that the Meiji Restoration
represented “not a ‘bourgeois revolution,’ as some historians say, but a
bureaucratic attempt to buy off such a revolution” (“Japan Heads for Disaster,”
12 July 1933). However, Trotsky viewed Japan as a full-fledged imperialist
power, standing on a qualitatively higher level of social and economic
development than semicolonies like China. He defended China against Japanese
imperialist invasion in the 1930s. A resolution adopted at the founding
conference of the Fourth International stated with regard to Japan: “Bourgeois
property relations and the capitalist system of exploitation, extending over
both the proletariat and the peasantry, decree revolutionary overthrow of the
ruling class and the establishment of the dictatorship of the proletariat as the
only reed of salvation for both workers and peasants” (“The War in the Far East
and the Revolutionary Perspectives,” September 1938, Documents of the Fourth
International).
Taking off from Trotsky’s 1933 comment about the Meiji Restoration,
the Spartacist Group Japan (SGJ), Japanese section of the International
Communist League, had the position that the Meiji Restoration represented an
“incomplete” bourgeois-democratic revolution. For example, the SGJ wrote that
“The Meiji Restoration was not a bourgeois revolution, but a defensive measure
by the feudal bureaucracy for themselves” (Spartacist [Japan] No. 16, May
1994).
This present article is the result of some extensive research and
discussion within the ICL on the development of Japanese capitalism and the
history of the early JCP, in the course of which the Japanese comrades have come
to change their understanding of the Meiji Restoration and its implications.
However, we recognize that our article is limited because the research is based
mainly on English-language sources, as well as some newly published material
from the Comintern archives (see endnote).
Social Origins of the Meiji Restoration
Japan’s revolution from above in the late 1860s resulted from the
intersection of two deeply rooted historical developments: the slow decay of
Japanese feudalism caused by its own inner contradictions and the violent
intrusion of Western imperialism in East Asia.
The Japanese feudal polity was marked by a curious dualism between
the emperor and the shogun (generalissimo or commander). The emperor was
universally recognized as the supreme authority of the Japanese nation. However,
throughout the history of medieval Japan real power was wielded by the
shogun, a member of one of the most powerful feudal clans. The emperor
remained secluded, often forcibly, in Kyoto, a semi-mystical figure uninvolved
in the actual course of political events.
In 1600, Tokugawa Ieyasu defeated his rivals in the famous battle
of Sekigahara and established the Tokugawa shogunate (or Bakufu), which
ruled Japan for the next two and a half centuries. Through a policy of rigid
national isolationism, Japan preserved its independence during the first phase
of Western imperialist expansion in the era of mercantile capitalism. The
Bakufu also effectively suppressed the warfare among the daimyo
(feudal lords) which had been endemic to medieval Japan. However, the very
successes and stability of the Tokugawa state set in motion social forces which
eventually led to its overthrow.
With an end to the continual warfare, the hereditary warrior caste,
the samurai, lost its traditional role in Japanese society. Barred from
engaging in trade, many samurai became impoverished and deeply alienated
from the existing order. Some became ronin (wandering men), or masterless
samurai, owing fealty to no lord and professing no fixed occupation.
The long Tokugawa peace, the Bakufu’s construction of a
network of roads connecting different parts of the country, and the development
of coastal shipping all facilitated a substantial and steady increase in
agricultural production and handicraft (pre-industrial) manufactures. The main
beneficiary of this economic growth were the shonin (merchants),
especially the big rice dealers of Osaka like the Mitsui family. Many a
daimyo and samurai found themselves deeply in debt to the powerful
merchant families.
However, the further development of mercantile capital in Japan was
blocked by the prohibitions on foreign trade, restrictions on the purchase and
sale of land and the division of the country into hundreds of han (feudal
domains), each with its own border guards and currency. By the first decades of
the 19th century, the frustrated ambitions of the great merchant houses and
their allies in the cities converged with the discontents of nationalistic,
modernizing elements among the samurai. Historians have called this the
union of “the yen with the sword.”
E. Herbert Norman wrote in 1940 a pioneering study on the origins
of modern Japan, Japan’s Emergence as a Modern State (Toronto: UBC Press,
2000 [1940]), which drew heavily on the rich historical scholarship of Japanese
Marxist intellectuals. Norman explained:
“The chonin [townspeople] felt that their own prosperity
was closely tied to that of the warrior and noble classes, their customers and
debtors. For this reason the chonin never dreamed of making a frontal
assault on feudalism as a system, although they were prepared to finance a
political movement against the Bakufu in concert with rival
feudal elements.” (emphasis in original)
The son of Canadian Protestant missionaries, Norman spent his
childhood in rural Japan in the 1910s and ’20s. Under the impact of the rise of
fascism in Germany in the early 1930s, he was attracted to the left and briefly
joined the British Communist Party while a student at Cambridge University. For
this, among other reasons, Norman’s book was buried, particularly by American
academics, during the Cold War. Then a member of the Canadian diplomatic corps,
Norman was hounded to his death by the American McCarthyites, finally committing
suicide in 1957.
According to the traditional feudal hierarchy, the peasants stood
below the samurai, but above artisans and merchants. The growth of trade
and a money economy undermined the traditional structure and stability of the
Japanese village, with a few peasants becoming richer and others falling into
penury. A growing population of urbanized (propertyless) manual laborers came
into being. Early 19th-century Japan saw a rising incidence of peasant revolts
against feudal exactions and also rice riots in the cities directed against
merchant speculators and the government officials who protected them.
The growing social tensions in late feudal Japan were brought to a
critical point, resulting in civil war, by the direct threat of Western military
conquest. In the 1840s, the Japanese ruling classes looked on with shock and
trepidation as Britain defeated and humiliated China in the Opium War, annexed
Hong Kong and reduced the “Celestial Kingdom”—the center of East Asian
civilization since time immemorial—to semicolonial subjugation. In 1853, an
American naval fleet under Commodore Perry forced its way into Tokyo Bay,
demanding trade concessions. Unable to resist militarily, the Tokugawa shogunate
agreed to unequal commercial treaties with the United States and the European
powers and granted Western nationals extraterritorial legal rights in Japan.
These concessions led to an organized opposition to the
Bakufu expressed in the slogan: “Revere the emperor! Expel the
barbarian!” In other words, only a strong central government ruled directly by
the emperor could preserve Japan’s independence. The anti-Bakufu forces were
concentrated in the domains of 86 tozama (“outside” lords), the historic
enemies of the Tokugawa dynasty. These oppositional han now came under
the de facto leadership of modernizing samurai who built up their
military strength along Western lines.
The decade-long maneuvers and struggle for power between the
Bakufu and the tozama—with four clans, Satsuma, Choshu, Tosa and
Hizen, in the leadership—culminated in 1868 in a brief civil war which ended
with the defeat of the Bakufu. Breaking sharply with Japanese feudal
tradition, Choshu enrolled peasants and other commoners into its army. The
victors established a new government in the name of the supreme authority of the
Emperor Meiji. Hence this historical event is called the Meiji Ishin
(Restoration). However, the leaders of the new regime mostly governed
independently of the emperor, who was seen to be above the political battles of
the time.
Over the next few years, this regime introduced a series of
measures amounting to a revolutionary transformation of broad scope: recognition
of the legal equality of all classes, abolition of feudal dress, establishment
of state schools, reform of the calendar, formal emancipation of the forebears
of the Burakumin (considered a pariah caste because they dealt with dead animals
and leather tanning), removal of the feudal ban on alienation and partition of
land, establishment of the freedom to choose one’s occupation, etc. Japan
imported the most modern industry and technology. In the 1870s, more than 2,000
experts—mathematicians, scientists, engineers—were recruited to teach the basic
sciences that made modern industry possible. For training in engineering,
government technical schools were established with foreign instructors, while
the best Japanese students were sent abroad to master the most up-to-date
techniques.
While the forces leading the Meiji Restoration were internal to
Japan, their success was strongly conditioned by favorable international
circumstances. The main rival Western powers were unable or unwilling to
intervene decisively at this critical juncture in Japan’s history. Tsarist
Russia, which had ambitions toward the Kurile Islands on Japan’s northern
fringes, was still recovering from its defeat at the hands of Britain and France
in the Crimean War of the 1850s. The United States was internally preoccupied
with the deep political fissures and profound socio-economic dislocations of its
own momentous Civil War a few years earlier. The interventions of Britain and
France in Japan in a sense cancelled each other out, with the latter supporting
the Bakufu and the former the anti-Tokugawa forces.
More generally, for all of these Western states China was the main
target and great prize in East Asia, with Japan regarded as relatively poor
pickings. As Norman put it, “It was the sprawling prostrate body of China which
acted as a shield for Japan against the mercantile and colonial greed of the
European Powers.” Thus in the historical short run, the Japanese ruling classes
had a wide latitude to radically restructure their state.
Toward a Dialectical Understanding of the Meiji Restoration
How can one characterize the Meiji Restoration as a bourgeois
revolution if it was not led by the bourgeoisie? The bourgeoisie did not
directly lead the French Revolution either—the Jacobins were led by lawyers like
Robespierre and other petty-bourgeois professionals, supported by the urban
artisan masses and land-hungry peasants. However, it was the commercial and
financial bourgeoisie who were in a position to benefit from the overthrow of
the monarchy and the abolition of feudal impediments to national economic
development, laying the basis for a nascent industrial bourgeoisie within two
generations. The lower samurai, who spearheaded the Meiji Restoration,
could legitimately be described as a military-bureaucratic caste or stratum. In
order to survive as a nationally independent ruling class, they had to transform
Japan into a modern industrial capitalist country and therewith foster the
development of an industrial bourgeoisie. Their policies and actions led within
two generations to the development of an industrial/financial bourgeoisie as the
dominant social class in Japan.
Here it is instructive to look at the Bismarckian “revolution from
above” in Germany. In doing so it is also necessary to recognize certain
fundamental differences, as well as important parallelisms, between Germany and
Japan in the late 19th century. Germany stood at a qualitatively higher level of
economic development, with a substantial industry and an already economically
dominant bourgeoisie which, however, confronted a rapidly growing, socially and
politically conscious proletariat.
The extension of the socio-economic achievements of the French
Revolution to western and southern Germany through military conquest under the
Napoleonic empire gave a powerful impetus to the development of industrial as
well as commercial capitalism. On the eve of the Revolution of 1848, Engels
wrote of the German bourgeoisie:
“Although its advance during the last thirty years has not been
nearly as great as that of the English and French bourgeoisie, it has
nevertheless established most branches of modern industry, in a few districts
supplanted peasant or petty-bourgeois patriarchalism, concentrated capital to
some extent, produced something of a proletariat, and built fairly long
stretches of railroad. It has at least reached the point of having either to go
further and make itself the ruling class or to renounce its previous conquests,
the point where it is the only class that can at the moment bring about progress
in Germany, can at the moment rule Germany.”
— “The Constitutional Question in Germany” (June 1847)
However, during the upheaval of 1848 the bourgeoisie’s fear that a
radical democratic revolution would be but a prelude to a “red revolution,”
centrally based on the urban working class, drove it into an alliance with the
forces of monarchical reaction. Marx and Engels concluded that the European
bourgeoisie had already turned reactionary. As a result, Marx ended his address
of the Central Authority to the Communist League in March 1850 with the famous
cry for “The Revolution in Permanence.”
With the further rapid development of industrial capitalism, the
main body of the German bourgeoisie formed an alliance with the Prussian landed
nobility (the Junkers), which laid the basis for Bismarck’s “revolution from
above” in the 1860s. Bismarck began as a political representative of the Junkers
and had been an extreme reactionary in the Revolution of 1848-49. But he
represented this feudal-derived class in the era of industrial capitalism, in
which Prussia confronted more advanced bourgeois states: Britain and France.
Bismarck came to understand that only the industrial/financial bourgeoisie could
transform Germany into a comparably advanced state and thereby ensure the
survival, and indeed prosperity, of the old landed classes as well.
In the late 1880s, Engels wrote in this regard:
“A person in Bismarck’s position and with Bismarck’s past, having
a certain understanding of the state of affairs, could not but realise that the
Junkers, such as they were, were not a viable class, and that of all the
propertied classes only the bourgeoisie could lay claim to a future, and that
therefore (disregarding the working class, an understanding of whose historical
mission we cannot expect of him) his new empire promised to be all the stabler,
the more he succeeded in laying the groundwork for its gradual transition to a
modern bourgeois state.”
—Engels, The Role of Force in History (1887-88)
The Prussian Junkers became large-scale agrarian capitalists and
the Hohenzollern monarchy operated effectively free of parliamentary control.
While the Reichstag (parliament) had some influence over domestic policies, it
had no effective control over foreign affairs and the military. As Engels wrote
in 1891: “The German empire is a monarchy with semi-feudal institutions, but
dominated ultimately by the economic interests of the bourgeoisie” (“Socialism
in Germany”).
Considered dialectically, the Meiji Restoration was led by a
bourgeoisie in the process of becoming. This understanding was expressed in one
of the earliest Soviet studies of the subject, written in 1920:
“We may conclude that Japan, having changed its economical
structure, still did not possess the class of bourgeoisie which could take over
the rule of the country. It was the class of feudal lords that remained in
power. They acknowledged the changes which had happened in Japan, rejected all
outmoded feudal norms and started the rapid development of capitalism.... Hence,
the term ‘revolution’ may be used in relation to the Meiji Ishin only
conventionally. It may be called ‘bourgeois’ only from the viewpoint of its
results, which does not mean at all that the bourgeoisie played the most
important role at that time.”
— O.V. Pletner, The History of the Meiji Era, quoted in
Julia Mikhailova, “Soviet-Japanese Studies on the Problem of the Meiji Ishin and
the Development of Capitalism in Japan,” in War, Revolution and Japan
(1993)
A Bourgeois-Democratic Revolution Was Precluded by History
For Marxists, a bourgeois-democratic revolution is centrally
defined by its socio-economic (i.e., class) content, not by a
change in the form of government. The classic bourgeois-democratic revolutions
in England in the 1640s and France in 1789-93 overthrew absolutist monarchies
that were the political organs of the landed nobility. Mobilizing the peasantry
and urban lower classes, the mercantile (i.e., pre-industrial) bourgeoisie
achieved political power through the Cromwellian Commonwealth in England and the
Jacobin regime and later Napoleonic empire in France.
To view the classic bourgeois-democratic revolutions as a template
for all subsequent capitalist development—as did the Mensheviks in their stagist
schema for tsarist Russia, and subsequently Stalin/Bukharin in the case of the
semicolonial countries—is ahistorical and undialectical. When in
July 1789 artisans, shopkeepers and day laborers in Paris stormed the Bastille,
France was the strongest absolutist (i.e., late feudal) state in Europe. The
revolution greatly enhanced the economic and military resources of the French
state, enabling Napoleon Bonaparte—a onetime protégé of Robespierre—to conquer
and transform much of Europe. The masses had to be mobilized to break a path for
capitalist development in France (and earlier in England). This was also
partially true in a somewhat later period in the United States and Italy. But it
is not true for Germany or Japan. There is no necessary connection between
democracy and the development of capitalism.
The “bourgeois revolutions from above” in late 19th-century Germany
and Japan were not exceptions to some historic “norm” set by the French
Revolution. They were instead the outcome of the intervening history since the
French Revolution. The only way for the ruling classes in Germany and Japan to
avoid invasion and subjugation by Britain, France or the United States was rapid
industrialization. They were able to propel their nations into the ranks of the
imperialist powers by clearing out the feudal obstacles to capitalist
development from above, in the process transforming themselves into capitalists.
By 1900, with the world and its markets more or less divided between the five
existing imperialist powers, that road was closed to other late developing
bourgeoisies.
Japan in the mid 19th century was a pre-industrial
(though in many ways relatively advanced) feudal state confronting far more
powerful industrializing capitalist states. It was the well-grounded fear of
succumbing to China’s fate that galvanized decisive sections of the Japanese
feudal nobility, especially the lower echelons of the samurai, to
overthrow the old order and restructure the Japanese economy and state along
Western lines. Though he himself viewed the Meiji Restoration as an “incomplete”
bourgeois revolution, E. Herbert Norman also understood that the conditions
confronting the Meiji rulers immediately after the revolution ruled out a
bourgeois-democratic road:
“The speed with which Japan had simultaneously to
establish a modern state, to build an up-to-date defense force in order to ward
off the dangers of invasion (which the favorable balance of world forces and the
barrier of China could not forever postpone), to create an industry on which to
base this armed force, to fashion an educational system suitable to an
industrial modernized nation, dictated that these important changes be
accomplished by a group of autocratic bureaucrats rather than by the mass of the
people working through democratic organs of representation.”
—Op. cit.
Could this social transformation have been accomplished by a
revolutionary upheaval? Let us assume that the civil war between the
Bakufu and the tozama had resulted in the mutual destruction or
disorganization of any effective military force in the hands of the feudal
nobility. A power vacuum formed, allowing a mass peasant rebellion, refusal to
pay tribute to the daimyo, and also uprisings of the lower classes in the
cities. In short, Japan was engulfed by revolutionary anarchy.
What would have been the historical outcome? The Japanese
daimyo and shonin would have invited and facilitated the military
intervention of the Western powers to suppress the peasant rebellion. In the
aftermath Japan would have been reduced to colonial or semicolonial subjugation.
A section of the daimyo, samurai and merchant class would have
been transformed into a comprador bourgeoisie, such as then existed in China,
totally subservient to the Western imperialists.
One need only look at the Taiping rebellion in China in the 1850s
and early 1860s. This massive peasant revolt, which lasted over a decade, took
over much of the Yangtze Valley and established a capital in the major city of
Nanjing. Since the decadent Manchu rulers were incapable of suppressing the
revolt, the Chinese gentry (landlord class) turned to the Western powers. An
American adventurer, Frederick Townsend Ward, and a British officer, Charles
“Chinese” Gordon, trained and commanded an elite Chinese force which finally
defeated the Taipings.
A peasant rebellion in Japan at this time, even if initially
successful, would have suffered a similar fate. This is not to say that
following the Meiji Restoration the future course of Japanese history was
predetermined for the next several decades. Some greater degree of social
egalitarianism and political liberalization was certainly possible in late 19th-
and early 20th-century Japan. But what was not possible was a radical
bourgeois-democratic revolution on the French model.
The 1873 Land Tax
The leaders of the Meiji Restoration expressed their intent to
modernize Japan with such slogans as “Prosperous Nation, Strong Military” and
“Increase Production, Promote Industry.” But how were these slogans translated
into reality, given that Japan at the time was far more economically backward
than the Western capitalist states that threatened its independence? In brief,
by maintaining an exceptionally high level of exploitation of the peasantry, but
now channeling the resulting economic surplus into the rapid construction of an
industrial-military complex. The 1873 Land Tax was the main mechanism in late
19th-century Japan for what Marx termed, in speaking of West Europe (centrally
England) in the 17th and 18th centuries, the “primitive accumulation of
capital.”
In 1871, the new Meiji regime, through a combination of military
threat and financial inducement, pressured the daimyo into “returning”
their han to the authority of the central government. They were
compensated with long-term government bonds. At the same time, the government
took over the stipends, though at a diminishing rate, which the former
daimyo had paid to their samurai. The Land Tax provided the bulk
of the revenue for the interest and redeemed principal on the government bonds
as well as the stipends to the former samurai.
In this way, the state treasury became a conduit between the
economic surplus extracted from the peasantry and a developing
industrial/financial bourgeoisie drawn from the former feudal nobility and the
old merchant class. By 1880, 44 percent of the stock of Japan’s national banks
was owned by former daimyo, and almost a third by former samurai.
These banks then went on to finance the rapid development of Japanese
industry.
The central role played by the state treasury in the initial
industrialization of Japan also resulted, paradoxically, from the restrictions
imposed upon Japanese economic policy by the Western imperialist powers. Under
the threat of American and British military action, in the late 1850s and ’60s
the Tokugawa shogunate signed unequal commercial treaties which prohibited Japan
from charging tariffs of more than 5 percent of the value of Western imports.
The Meiji government was therefore unable to protect its newly developing
industries behind high tariff barriers, as Germany and the United States were
able to do in the late 19th century. Instead the Japanese ruling class had
recourse to direct government ownership and subsidies.
American economic historian G.C. Allen stated: “There was scarcely
any important Japanese industry of the Western type during the latter decades of
the nineteenth century which did not owe its establishment to state initiative”
(A Short Economic History of Modern Japan [1981]). By the end of the
century, almost all state-owned industrial enterprises and other assets had been
sold off, usually at nominal prices, to politically favored entrepreneurs. The
most successful of these formed the zaibatsu, the great
industrial/financial empires like Mitsubishi and Mitsui which came to dominate
and continue to dominate the Japanese economy.
Just as Meiji Japan saw the rise of a new class of
industrial/financial capitalists, it also saw the rise of a new class of
agrarian exploiters. As increasing numbers of peasants were unable to meet their
tax payments and/or repay their debts at usurious interest rates, they were
forced to sell all or part of their land, typically to rich peasants or village
merchant/moneylenders. Many were forced to send their daughters to work for
textile manufacturers in the city, thus providing workers for early Japanese
industry. An advance on the daughters’ wages would be loaned to the peasant
families to meet their tax burden. Interest and principal on these loans,
together with payments for the daughters’ food and lodging, consumed most of, if
not more than the wages, forcing rural families further into debt. By 1903, 44
percent of all agricultural land in Japan was worked by tenant farmers who paid
over 50 percent of their crop, usually in kind, as rent to the landlords.
Here it should be emphasized that the landlord class in early
20th-century Japan was not in the main derived from the old feudal
nobility. An American student of Japanese agrarian history explained:
“Although most former daimyo remained wealthy and as members of
the House of Peers gained a direct voice in the political system after 1890,
they were no longer a landed aristocracy with the power to control local
affairs.... They invested in forest land, in new industrial enterprises, and
perhaps most of all, in banking. Even if part of their income was derived from
agriculture, it was generally a small part, overshadowed by their other
interests. They no longer exercised political control over the land they owned,
and although they were represented in the House of Peers, that body was at no
time the center of political power.”
— Ann Waswo, Japanese Landlords: The Decline of a Rural
Elite (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977)
The lower house of the Diet, which approved the government budget,
was elected by the wealthiest male property owners.
A new landlord class arose through the economic
differentiation of the peasantry and other sectors of the rural petty
bourgeoisie. In the 1930s, a visiting American academic contemptuously described
typical Japanese landlords as “lately merchants, owners of inns and brothels,
masters of road repair crews, and persons of similar status” (quoted in
ibid.). Furthermore, wealthier landlords increasingly reinvested the
rents collected from tenant farmers in bank deposits, government bonds and
corporate securities. By the 1920s, the wealthiest families in rural Japan were
getting as much, if not more, of their income from their financial assets as
from their agricultural holdings.
Thus the landlord class in interwar Japan was in no sense feudal or
semi-feudal, but was thoroughly integrated economically and in many cases
socially into the dominant urban industrial economy.
The 1889 Meiji Constitution
While the Meiji Restoration was a revolution from above, it
necessarily produced powerful reverberations from below, awakening among the
peasants and urban laborers expectations of a better and freer life. The two
decades following were a period of great social and political turbulence.
For the first time in Japanese history, women rebelled against
their traditional subservience and demanded democratic rights. Several villages
and municipalities set up local councils, and women were allowed to run for
office (provided they had their husbands’ permission). Women militants toured
the country giving speeches calling for suffrage, birth control and the right of
inheritance.
The forces of social radicalism found their main organized
expression in the People’s Rights Movement, which demanded a democratic,
representative government. Rural agitation centered around this movement
climaxed in 1884, in a rebellion in the mountainous district of Chichibu in
central Japan, northwest of Tokyo. Peasants sacked the homes of moneylenders,
stormed government offices to destroy debt records, and intimidated the rich
into making donations for poor relief. The uprising was crushed by the army and
shortly thereafter the People’s Rights Movement was broken through a combination
of state repression and the government’s success in buying off many of its
leaders.
The consolidation of a strong repressive state apparatus laid the
political basis for the 1889 Meiji Constitution, which was modeled on that of
imperial Germany. Government ministers were appointed by the emperor (actually
by the Meiji oligarchs acting in the emperor’s name), not by the majority party
in the Diet.
Taking the concept of ie (family household system) as the
basis for the new hierarchical social structure, the 1898 Civil Code adopted the
Confucian-based values of the samurai class as its foundation. The
emperor stood at the apex as the head of the entire nation and, in turn, the
husband was absolute ruler over his individual family. Primogeniture was
mandated for all classes. Wives were treated as minors, and the code insisted
that “cripples and disabled persons and wives cannot undertake any legal
action.” Women were banned from participating in political activities. Yet women
workers were the backbone of the developing industrial economy—especially in the
textile industry, which produced 60 percent of the foreign exchange in the
latter part of the 19th century and in which women made up 60 to 90 percent of
the workforce.
The emperor system enshrined in the constitution was
not a surviving feudal institution representing the interests of a
landed nobility (which no longer existed at all). Rather, the traditional
authority and mystical aura surrounding the emperor were now used to legitimize
a state apparatus which first and foremost acted to protect and further the
interests of the industrial and financial capitalists, represented at their apex
by the zaibatsu.
World War I and Industrialization
The First World War changed the structure of the Japanese economy
and working class, while the 1917 Russian Bolshevik Revolution changed the
political character of the Japanese left. Prior to 1914 Japan’s heavy industrial
sector, closely tied to the military, remained dependent on government financial
support. Japan exported light manufactures—mainly cotton textiles and silk—and
imported industrial machinery and much of its steel from Europe and the United
States.
The war totally disrupted the existing pattern of world trade,
enabling Japan to move up into the first rank of industrial capitalist
countries. A Japanese academic Marxist, Takahashi Masao, pointed out:
“With the European nations devoting themselves entirely to the war
effort, the arteries of commodity exchange in the world economy were completely
stopped....
“Although there was a great difference in the scope and degree of
industrialization, both America and Japan were able to rapidly and extensively
develop their economies. They were in a similar position in that they were both
able to develop those kinds of manufacturing for which they had previously been
dependent on Europe. And thus they functioned as suppliers of industrial
products for underdeveloped areas, as well as of goods of various kinds for the
belligerent nations.”
— Modern Japanese Economy Since the Meiji Restoration
(1967)
Between 1914 and 1921, Japan’s output of steel doubled; the
production of electrical motors increased in value from 9 million to 34 million
yen. Overall, industrial production multiplied almost
fivefold!
This brought about a corresponding change in the social weight and
character of the Japanese working class. The proportion of the manufacturing
labor force engaged in heavy industry, characterized by large-scale factories,
increased from 13.6 percent in 1910 to 24.2 percent by the end of the war. In
the early 1920s there was a large permanently urbanized industrial proletariat
in Japan, heavily male, employed in steel mills, shipyards, chemical factories,
auto and truck plants, etc. Nonetheless, Japan was the only major industrial
capitalist country in the interwar period in which peasant struggle against
landlords was an important arena of social conflict.
The changes in workforce composition combined with the inflation
that accompanied the World War I industrial expansion resulted in an upsurge in
labor militancy and social unrest, capped by the 1918 “Rice Riots.” The price of
rice doubled from 1917 to 1918, and after the wives of fishermen in Toyama
Prefecture raided rice shops in August 1918, rice riots spread throughout the
country. The government called out troops to quell the riots, killing more than
100 protesters. The surge of unrest led to a mass movement for universal
suffrage. The poll tax was decreased in 1919 (increasing the voter rolls from
one to three million), but the government refused to grant universal suffrage.
Strikes and labor unrest also spread, and Japanese socialists began to gain
influence in some major Japanese unions.
Early Japanese Communists
Early Japanese Socialists were largely Christian and confined to
small propaganda groups. After 1906 an anarcho-syndicalist current developed,
but its membership periodically collaborated with the more reformist-minded
Socialist movement. In 1910 the best-known anarchist, Kotoku Shusui, and 26
supporters were arrested and charged with plotting to assassinate the emperor
and his family. Following the so-called Great Treason Trial, Kotoku was executed
in 1911, along with eleven others, including his companion Kanno Suga. After
this the organized left virtually ceased to exist.
Katayama Sen, a leader of the evolutionary, pacifist wing of
Japanese socialism, had previously spent time in the United States and returned
there in 1914. There he worked with the Socialist Party, took a special interest
in the fight against black oppression, and eventually founded the League of
Japanese Socialists. Won to the Bolshevik banner after the Russian Revolution,
Katayama sent many League members back to Japan to help found a Japanese
Communist Party. He himself went to Moscow in late 1921, playing a major role in
the Comintern’s dealings with Japan from 1922. However, the extent to which
Katayama broke from his Christian, pacifist origins remains questionable. During
the Stalinist degeneration he espoused the bureaucracy’s various twists and
turns with unfailing loyalty. In 1928 Trotsky wrote, “Katayama is by nature a
complete mistake.... His conceptions form a progressivism very lightly colored
by Marxism” (“Who Is Leading the Comintern Today?”, September 1928).
Nevertheless, the supporters he won in the United States played an important
role in the early Japanese Communist movement.
The core leadership of the early JCP, however, came from the
anarcho-syndicalists like Yamakawa Hitoshi, Sakai Toshihiko and Arahata Kanson,
who began to propagate Bolshevism (as they understood it) as early as May 1919.
They were joined not only by Katayama’s supporters, but also by individual
student recruits from a burgeoning post-World War I academic Marxist trend that
was tolerated by the government for most of the decade. Despite the authority
won by anarcho-syndicalists in the union movement after the war, the early
Communists had very slim roots in the working class.
Japan was the first imperialist country to invade the territory of
the world’s first workers state in April 1918. Its troops were the last to leave
in November 1922, and even then Japan retained control of Sakhalin Island,
agreeing to evacuate its troops from Northern Sakhalin only in 1925, when
diplomatic relations with Soviet Russia were finally established. Japan
continued to occupy Southern Sakhalin until its troops were driven out by the
Red Army at the end of World War II.
While the Bolsheviks made efforts to establish contact with
Japanese militants attracted to the Russian Revolution’s banner, foreign
military intervention and the Civil War, which raged in the Russian Far East,
made such contact extremely difficult. Moreover, Yamakawa and Sakai were
originally reticent to establish contact with the Comintern, fearing to draw the
attention of the very efficient Japanese secret police. It was not until April
1921, when the Korean Communist Yi Chung-rim, who had been a student at Meiji
University, was sent to Tokyo by the CI that Yamakawa agreed to establish a
“Preparatory Committee” for a Japanese Communist Party. At this point the
Japanese Communists constituted a loose circle that overlapped with the
anarcho-syndicalists.
The opening of the Comintern Archives in Moscow has made available
a wealth of new material on the Japanese Communist Party, which sheds light on
the early years of the party. We publish three of the newly available JCP
documents as appendices to this article, including the April 1921 Manifesto of
the Preparatory Committee of the JCP, which was authored by Yamakawa, working
with Katayama protégé Kondo Eizo. The 1921 Manifesto makes clear that the early
Japanese Communists considered the Meiji Restoration to have laid the basis for
a capitalist Japan and did not subscribe to a two-stage schema.
The first delegation from the Japanese Socialist/anarchist milieu
did not arrive in Moscow until late 1921. They came to participate in the First
Congress of the Toilers of the Far East, which took place in January-February
1922. The Congress included not only Communists, but also bourgeois-nationalist
forces (the Chinese Guomindang was present), journalists and other disparate
forces. Bukharin, Zinoviev and Stalin were appointed by the Russian Political
Bureau to be the Commission in charge of directing the Congress. Zinoviev
convened the event and played a very public role there. Bukharin helped draft
and present the resolution on Japan. Stalin met with the Japanese delegation and
is credited in at least one account with being among those who won over some of
the anarcho-syndicalists. Stalin retained his interest in the Far East for the
rest of the decade, and it is clear that he worked closely with Bukharin in
developing the “two-stage revolution” dogma and pushing it upon the Communist
parties of the East.
The Congress was held on the eve of Lenin’s first stroke and just
as Stalin, Zinoviev and Kamenev were beginning to establish their alliance
against Trotsky. The Zinovievist school of politics as bombast and maneuver was
infecting the Comintern. However, it had not yet triumphed. The “Tasks of the
Japanese Communists” adopted at the Congress clearly states, “A proletarian
dictatorship, the replacement of the military-plutocratic monarchy with the
power of the Soviets—that is the goal of the Communist Party.” At the same time,
the resolution asserted that “the configuration of class forces in Japan allows
us to expect the success of a radical democratic overturn” and argued that the
JCP orient itself accordingly.
The resolutions and proceedings of the First Congress of the
Toilers of the Far East introduced certain ambiguities into the tasks of the
Asian Communist parties, but this was by no means a full-blown schema of
“two-stage revolution.” The CI leadership did not recognize that the disruption
of trade with Europe during WWI had led, not just to an expansion of Japan’s
industrial base, but also to the development of a burgeoning industrial
proletariat in colonial and semicolonial countries like China and India. Thus,
the main report on the national-colonial question, delivered by G. Safarov, was
based on the premise that the proletariat in most Eastern countries did not have
the social weight to play a leading role in a revolutionary upsurge. Japan was
recognized as an exception to this pattern—a full-blown imperialist country with
a proletariat which was the key to liberating the entire East. Safarov insisted
that the Japanese proletariat must ally itself with the nations struggling to
liberate themselves from Japanese imperialism. He called for the absolute
political independence of the proletariat from the bourgeois-nationalist forces
with whom they might collaborate.
The JCP and “Two-Stage Revolution”
The Japanese Communist Party was formally founded in July 1922,
some six months after the Congress of the Toilers of the Far East completed its
work. One month later, in August 1922, the Comintern made the decision that the
young Communist Party of China should enter the Guomindang. Three months later,
in November, during the Fourth Congress of the Communist International, Bukharin
authored a draft program of the Japanese party which did not mention the Meiji
Restoration, let alone seek to evaluate its import. He wrote:
“Japanese capitalism still demonstrates characteristics of former
feudal relationships. The greater part of the land is today in the hands of
semifeudal big landlords....
“Remnants of feudal relationships are manifested in the structure
of the state, which is controlled by a bloc consisting of a definite part of the
commercial and industrial capitalists and of the big landlords. The semifeudal
character of state power is clearly shown in the important and leading role of
the peers and in the basic features of the constitution. Under such conditions
the opposition to state power emanates not only from the working class,
peasants, and petty bourgeoisie, but also from a great segment of the
liberalistic bourgeoisie, who are opposed to the existing government.”
— “Draft Platform of the Japanese Communist Party,” November 1922,
published in George M. Beckmann and Okubo Genji, The Japanese Communist
Party, 1922-1945 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1969)
The program went on to insist:
“The party of the working class cannot remain indifferent to a
struggle against the imperial government, even though such a struggle may be
conducted under democratic slogans. The task of the Communist Party is to
constantly intensify the general movement, emphasize all slogans, and win the
dominant position in the movement during the struggle against the existing
government.
“Only after this first direct task has been fulfilled and some of
the former allies have begun to move to the side of the defeated class and
groups should the Japanese Communist Party strive to advance the revolution,
deepen it, and make efforts toward the acquisition of power by soviets of
workers and peasants.”
—Ibid.
The standard histories of Japanese Communism do not mention,
however, that there was another draft JCP program written two months prior to
Bukharin’s. This draft (published as an appendix here) was authored in
Japan by Arahata and Sakai. Arahata and Sakai label Japan “the Germany
of the East,” and their program begins with the clear statement that “The
Communist Party of Japan, a section of the Third Communist International, is an
illegal, proletarian political party, whose aim is the overthrow of the
Capitalist regime through the establishment of the Dictatorship of the
Proletariat based on the Soviet Power.” There is not a hint of stagism here.
Bukharin’s draft treats the democratic program it puts forward as a
temporary agenda for the Communist Party during the struggle to overthrow the
“existing government”—as if by draping itself in democratic clothing the JCP
could fool a wing of the rabidly anti-Communist Japanese bourgeoisie into
collaborating with it! The Arahata and Sakai draft, in contrast, correctly (if
abstractly) calls for combining the struggle for bourgeois-democratic rights
with the struggle for proletarian revolution to overthrow the capitalist system
as a whole.
Bukharin’s 1922 draft was greeted with significant opposition in
the JCP and was never officially adopted by the party. We publish as our third
appendix a May 1923 report by Arahata, written for the Third Enlarged Plenum of
the Comintern Executive Committee (ECCI) held in June, which describes the
dispute that developed in the JCP over Bukharin’s draft. This report was
published in Russian in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan, 1917-1941
and to our knowledge has not previously been available to students of Japanese
Communism.
As is apparent from Arahata’s report, at least some of the
opposition to Bukharin’s draft was due to residual anarcho-syndicalist
prejudices. Active in a series of increasingly violent strikes in 1921 and 1922,
the JCP continued to collaborate with the anarcho-syndicalists in the Sodomei,
the main trade-union federation. The cadre who went on to form the JCP had
ignored the struggle for universal suffrage; the question of whether or not to
even support the suffrage demand was under debate in the party as late as the
end of 1923 (when Yamakawa finally abandoned his opposition to it). Reformist
impulses were apparently also in play: Sakai at least did not want to raise the
demand for the abolition of the emperor system, fearing that this would bring
down further state repression on the young party.
It is clear from newly available Comintern documents that the
disparate forces that came together to form the JCP never gelled into a real
collective. The early debate between the pro-Bolshevik and anarcho-syndicalist
elements was never fought out to a conclusion; nor was the dispute on universal
suffrage ever resolved. The decisive lesson of the Russian Revolution—the need
for a programmatically homogenous party of professional revolutionaries—was
clearly not assimilated by the early JCP leaders. The party did not have a
central organ which carried the party’s line; the closest thing was
Zen’ei (Vanguard) which carried only signed articles and was seen as
Yamakawa’s personal responsibility. Personal animosities often overlapped with
political disputes and muddied the issues. The young JCP desperately needed
education and help in fighting through its differences and forging a political
line and cadre committed to implement it. But in 1922-23 the CI was already
beginning its slide toward degeneration and did not provide the kind of
political clarity that had been given to the young and fractious American
Communist movement from 1919-1922 (see James P. Cannon and the Early Years of
American Communism: Selected Writings and Speeches, 1920-1928 [New York:
Prometheus Research Library, 1992]).
While Japan was not “semi-feudal,” the undemocratic nature of its
transition from feudalism to capitalism continued to reverberate in a myriad of
ways. The government promised to introduce universal male suffrage at the end of
1923; the law wasn’t promulgated until 1925 and then the vote was only granted
to males over the age of 25. At the same time, there was an
increase in repressive measures. The 1925 Peace Preservation Law
made it illegal to participate in any organization with the “objective of
altering the national polity or the form of government, or denying the system of
private ownership” (quoted in Beckmann and Okubo, op. cit.). A resolution
of the Privy Council motivated the new law: “Since putting universal suffrage
into effect will result in a worsening of dangerous ideas, the government must
establish and put into effect laws and regulations for the rigid control [of
dangerous ideas] and must exert itself to prevent evil abuses and practices”
(quoted in Peter Duus, Party Rivalry and Political Change in Taisho Japan
[1968]). The Peace Preservation Law was the legal basis for the vicious
repression against the JCP through WWII.
With the feudal legacy shaping so many aspects of the Japanese
bourgeois order, the weight of democratic demands is necessarily greater in the
proletarian revolutionary program. From its inception in 1988 the Spartacist
Group Japan has called for the abolition of the emperor system and the
establishment of a workers republic in Japan (our British section also calls for
the abolition of the monarchy and a federation of workers republics in the
British Isles). Unfortunately, the idea of a workers republic, a slogan which
had been raised by the Irish revolutionary James Connolly as early as 1898,
seems to have been absent from the lexicon of the early Communist
International.
The CI’s “Workers and Peasants Party” Orientation and the JCP’s
Liquidation
The political lines were muddied further in 1923 by the CI
leadership’s insistence that the JCP form a legal “workers and peasants” party,
which was to include representatives of the liberal bourgeoisie. This was part
of a general orientation toward such parties, including in the U.S., pushed by
the Comintern under Zinoviev’s leadership. The model of such a workers and
peasants party was Chiang Kai-shek’s bourgeois-nationalist Guomindang (a version
of which the CI leadership was proposing for Japan), which drowned the Chinese
Revolution of 1925-27 in blood.
From the start, Trotsky fought the “two-class” party perspective.
In 1928, he subjected the misleadership of the world Communist movement to a
scathing and comprehensive attack in his Critique of the Comintern draft program
written by Bukharin. Trotsky’s Critique, a defining document of world Trotskyism
now known as The Third International After Lenin, contains an important
section, “On the Reactionary Idea of ‘Two-Class Workers and Peasants Parties’
for the Orient”:
“Marxism has always taught, and Bolshevism too, accepted and
taught, that the peasantry and proletariat are two different classes, that it is
false to identify their interests in capitalist society in any way, and that a
peasant can join the Communist Party only if, from the property viewpoint, he
adopts the views of the proletariat....
“The younger the proletariat, the fresher and more direct its
‘blood ties’ with the peasantry, the greater the proportion of the peasantry to
the population as a whole, the greater becomes the importance of the struggle
against any form of ‘two-class’ political alchemy. In the West the idea of a
workers and peasants party is simply ridiculous. In the East it is fatal. In
China, India, and Japan this idea is mortally hostile not only to the hegemony
of the proletariat in the revolution but also to the most elementary
independence of the proletarian vanguard.”
Arahata spoke on the floor of the June 1923 ECCI Plenum against the
perspective of forming a legal workers and peasants party in Japan. Zinoviev
responded, “We shall insist that our Japanese comrades learn a lesson from the
American Communist Party, and try to organize a legal Communist party in Japan.”
The American Communist movement had gone underground in response to a wave of
arrests and deportations in 1919-20 known as the “Palmer Raids,” but conditions
quickly returned to the norms of bourgeois democracy as the American ruling
class figured out that its rule was not fundamentally threatened. The legal
party formed by the American Communists in December 1921 was the Workers Party,
which had an openly communist program. (The American Workers Party also went on
to follow CI directives in 1923 and join in the founding of a short-lived
Farmer-Labor Party on a populist program.)
Replying to Zinoviev, Arahata correctly argued, “The case of the
American Party is not the same as with us.... Our Party is a secret organization
not because we want underground work but the situation compels us to be so”
(transcript of Arahata’s speech on 14 June 1923, in the Comintern archives in
the Russian State Archive of Socio-Political History). Japan in 1923 was not a
bourgeois democracy nor about to become one. The government promised to
introduce expanded suffrage that year, but the first election held under
universal (male) suffrage didn’t occur until 1928. A legal Communist Party was
not possible. Indeed, a legal party could not even call for abolition of the
emperor system.
As if to mock Zinoviev’s fatuous remark, the Japanese government
struck out with a wave of arrests of Japanese Communists in June 1923, on the
eve of a meeting between Soviet diplomat Adolf Joffe and Japanese government
representatives in Tokyo. The severe repression cut short the discussion of
Bukharin’s draft program. Joffe had been careful not to get involved with the
JCP (the Bolshevik leadership had evolved a correct and necessary separation
between the Comintern’s revolutionary activities and the diplomacy of the Soviet
state). But the arrests were obviously meant as a statement of hostility to any
red influence in Japan. At the time, powerful bourgeois circles opposed all
negotiations with the Soviet state. Though Joffe remained in Tokyo for several
more months, his negotiations were unsuccessful.
A few leading Japanese Communists were able to escape arrest and
get out of Japan, establishing a Japanese Bureau in Vladivostok in August 1923
with the approval of the Comintern. In fact, an émigré center was a vital
continuing necessity for the JCP. The party needed a leadership collective out
of reach of the Japanese state in order to produce a regular newspaper in
Japanese, as the Russian revolutionary Marxists had in an earlier period
published the newspaper Iskra (Spark) and the theoretical journal
Zarya (Dawn) to smuggle into the tsarist empire from European exile. A
stable JCP exile center would have been able to organize political debate,
collect information, and keep contact with those working underground in Japan.
Constant political debate over the real work of the party is a crucial aspect of
forging revolutionary communist parties.
However, the CI Japanese Bureau had barely begun functioning when a
horrific earthquake devastated much of Tokyo on 1 September 1923. In its wake,
the country was shaken by pogroms in which over 6,000 Koreans and hundreds of
Chinese were massacred. Communists, anarchists and labor leaders were hunted
down and killed; some were murdered in police stations. A wave of arrests of
leftist and labor leaders followed. In the aftermath, the Comintern made the
criminal decision to order most of the Japanese cadre in Vladivostok back to
Japan, thereby liquidating the Japanese Bureau and ending any chance of
establishing a stable political and organizational basis for the JCP.
At that time, all the attention of the CI leaders was focused on a
potential proletarian revolution in Germany. Those who made the decision to
liquidate the Japanese Bureau, knowing the full extent of the carnage and
arrests in Japan, wantonly neglected the need to create and preserve a
programmatically coherent JCP leadership like that which had been forged in
exile by the Russian Marxists, first under Plekhanov, and later by the
Bolsheviks under Lenin. More concerned with Soviet diplomatic initiatives than
preserving the JCP leadership, G. Voitinsky of the CI’s Eastern Bureau sent a
directive to the party that concluded:
“The drawing together of Japan and Soviet Russia after the
catastrophe must be made the most popular slogan among the masses of Japan,
since it is only from Soviet Russia that unselfish aid can come in the form of
raw materials needed for Japanese production. The party must pose the drawing
together of Japan and Russia as the alternative to the economic and political
enslavement of Japan by Anglo-American capital.”
— “Directive Telegram by G. Voitinsky to JCP,” 14 September 1923,
published in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan, 1917-1941 (our
translation)
The Japanese cadre were sent back to Japan with no confidence that
they would have an impact. The ECCI representative to the Japanese Bureau, I.I.
Feinberg, wrote:
“I believe that activists are better sent to work in the country
than kept idle in Vladivostok.
“From the information that we do have it is clear that the
earthquake is fraught with the most severe economic consequences and will place
Japan into dependence on foreign capital.... We need to take this fact into
account in our policies. I believe that the instructions we prepared work
towards this end. The only question is how to realize them. Speaking frankly, I
don’t have any great optimism. Our forces in Japan are still quite weak and
inexperienced, so it doesn’t make sense to expect very much from them.”
— “Letter by I.I. Feinberg to G.N. Voitinsky,” 20 September 1923,
published in ibid. (our translation)
This criminal decision set the JCP up to be destroyed by repeated
waves of state repression.
The Japanese Communists, many of whom were released from prison
just before the earthquake hit, were in no position to lead any kind of public
campaign. The arrests had devastated the tiny party; the earthquake’s
destruction compounded the problems (for example, the party’s illegal press was
destroyed).
Instead of following the CI’s instructions to increase their public
activity, the leading Japanese Communists made a decision to
liquidate the JCP in favor of concentrating their efforts on
forming a legal workers and peasants party. Yamakawa, who seems to have done a
political about-face at this time, abandoning his remaining anarcho-syndicalist
prejudices in favor of the fight for universal suffrage and a parliamentarist
approach, was the ideological inspirer of the liquidation. The JCP was formally
liquidated in March 1924; it was not reconstituted until December 1926. In the
interim the Japanese Communist movement functioned in loosely coordinated
circles, overlapping with the academic Marxist milieu, but under the ostensible
direction of a central bureau.
The Comintern opposed the liquidation of the JCP from the moment
the news reached Moscow. Katayama and other CI leaders mobilized to organize
Yamakawa’s opponents (among whom numbered, at least initially, Arahata) to
re-establish the JCP. But the liquidation was simply the logical political
conclusion of Zinoviev’s insistence that the JCP concentrate on legal political
activity in the form of a workers and peasants party. During the period of
liquidation the Japanese Communists—both the supporters of Yamakawa and the
supporters of the CI—joined the Japan Peasant Union and Sodomei trade-union
federation in forming two workers and peasants parties. The first was dissolved
by the government immediately after it was founded. The second, Rodo Nominto
(Labor-Farmer Party), was formed in March 1926. The reformist Sodomei leadership
withdrew from Rodo Nominto within months, refusing to cooperate any longer with
the Communists, and formed its own farmer- labor party. This left Rodo Nominto
as a legal, “democratic” front group of the Communists. Yamakawa and Sakai were
active in Rodo Nominto, even as they refused to join in any efforts to
reconstitute the JCP.
Continued Controversy over Meiji Restoration and “Two-Stage
Revolution”
The controversy over Bukharin’s 1922 draft was never formally
resolved; nonetheless, the two-stage schema was adopted as the official program
of the JCP. Even so, the nature of the Meiji Restoration and the coming
revolution in Japan continued to be a source of controversy. Fukumoto Kazuo, who
gained leadership of the Japanese Communist movement in 1926-27, argued that the
Japanese Constitution of 1889 (not the Meiji Restoration) constituted Japan’s
bourgeois-democratic revolution, though this “was artfully concealed from the
masses.” Fukumoto correctly noted that the Japanese bourgeoisie had turned
reactionary, and he asserted that the Japanese state “has today developed in
itself the germ of fascist dictatorship.” Too much of an independent mind for
Moscow’s liking, Fukumoto was deposed, falsely accused of being a
“Trotskyist.”
In 1927 new programmatic theses on Japan were adopted by the
Comintern. Again this was authored by Bukharin. This lengthy and contradictory
document argued: “The revolution of 1868 opened the path for capitalist
development in Japan. Political power, however, remained in the hands of the
feudal elements.” Bukharin now had to admit that the period since the Meiji
Restoration had seen “the transformation of the old Japanese state into a
bourgeois state.” In contradistinction to the 1922 draft program, he wrote that
“Japan is governed by a bloc of the bourgeoisie and landlords—a bloc under the
hegemony of the bourgeoisie. This being so, illusions that the bourgeoisie can
in any way be utilized as a revolutionary factor, even during the first stage of
the bourgeois-democratic revolution, must be abandoned” (“Theses on Japan
Adopted in the Session of the Presidium of the Executive Committee of the
Comintern on July 15, 1927,” in Beckmann and Okubo, op.cit.). Yet the
1927 theses still set as the aim of the JCP a bourgeois-democratic revolution
which would “rapidly grow into a socialist revolution”!
The 1927 theses provoked an open split with founding Communists
Yamakawa, Sakai and Arahata, who formed the Rono-ha (Labor-Farmer Faction). They
opposed the two-stage schema, insisting that the coming revolution in Japan
would be a proletarian one. But far from being a left opposition to Stalinist
opportunism, the Rono-ha faction insisted that the activity of Japanese
Communists be limited to legal work under the guise of a workers and peasants
party. The debate between Rono-ha and what became known as Koza-ha (the official
pro-Moscow party) on the development and nature of Japanese capitalism went on
for years and encompassed thousands of pages. But it is clear that Rono-ha’s
insistence that the bourgeoisie ruled in Japan, while correct, was largely a
theoretical justification for its refusal to call for the abolition of the
emperor system or engage in any other illegal activity. Acknowledging Rono-ha’s
willingness to stay within the limits set by the Japanese bourgeoisie, the state
allowed Rono-ha supporters to function legally until 1937, while savagely
repressing the JCP. Arahata and Yamakawa played leading roles in forming the
Japanese Socialist Party under the U.S. Occupation in 1945 (Sakai died in
1933).
Even after the split with Rono-ha, the question of a stagist
perspective was not settled within the JCP. In 1931, after Stalin had purged
Bukharin from the CI leadership and embarked on the sectarian adventurism and
left posturing of the Third Period, the JCP developed new programmatic theses
which described the Meiji Restoration as “a bourgeois-democratic revolution that
paved the way for the development of capitalism” and argued that the coming
Japanese revolution would be a “proletarian revolution that involves extensive
bourgeois-democratic tasks” (“The Political Theses of the Japanese Communist
Party, April-June 1931,” ibid.).
The hint of clarity provided by the 1931 theses did not, however,
last very long. Frightened by the Japanese invasion of Manchuria, the Stalinist
bureaucrats in the Kremlin refused to give up the illusion that a more
Soviet-friendly bourgeois regime could come to exist in Japan. The CI demanded
that the 1931 theses be thrown out. New theses on Japan adopted in 1932 argued
for the “overthrow of the monarchy by the victorious people’s revolution,” after
which “the main task of the Communist Party will be the struggle for the rapid
development of the bourgeois-democratic revolution into a socialist revolution”
(“Theses on the Situation in Japan and the Tasks of the Communist Party, May
1932,” ibid.). By this time, state persecution had so devastated the JCP
that it had virtually ceased to exist. The party was revived only in the
aftermath of Japan’s defeat in World War II.
Did the American Occupation Carry Out a “Supplementary Bourgeois
Revolution” in Japan?
The JCP used the two-stage schema as part of its justification for
initially supporting the post-WWII Occupation led by American imperialism, which
had indiscriminately firebombed most major cities in Japan and leveled Hiroshima
and Nagasaki with atom bombs. The JCP’s groveling effort to ingratiate itself
with the Allied authorities also represented the continuation of the support
which pro-Moscow parties around the world had given to the so-called
“democratic” imperialist war effort after Germany invaded the USSR in 1941. The
American Communist Party condemned U.S. workers who went on strike during the
war as allies of Hitler and the Mikado (the emperor) and supported the
internment of Japanese Americans. In 1945, the American CP hailed the atom
bombing of Hiroshima and Nagasaki!
The JCP hailed the Occupation authorities for moving against the
so-called “feudalistic elements” of the Japanese ruling elite. In late 1945, a
veteran JCP cadre, Yamamoto Masami, exulted that under the Occupation, “the
military cliques were eliminated, the bureaucratic cliques were finally losing
their relative independence,...the so-called familistic zaibatsu were also
beginning to be dissolved, and even the landownership of parasitic landlords was
being touched” (quoted in Germaine Hoston, Marxism and the Crisis of
Development in Prewar Japan [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986]).
The JCP retained a conciliatory approach to General Douglas MacArthur and his
occupation forces even after the Cold War began in earnest in 1947. The Japanese
Stalinists did not call for an end to the occupation until Moscow publicly
denounced them for not doing so in 1950, and then they did so in the name of
Japanese nationalism. In the 1970s, the JCP broke with both Moscow and Beijing
in favor of overt social democracy.
The view of the American Occupation as some kind of “democratic”
revolution remains the predominant view on the reformist Japanese left. A few
years ago, the journal of the Trotsky Research Institute (TRI) wrote:
“The postwar reforms that were carried out by the American
Occupation army were on the one hand almost thoroughgoing bourgeois reforms in a
country that had a belated industrial structure and a strong state that was
invasion hungry while simultaneously being in revolutionary turmoil. It was a
situation where [in the prewar period] landowners ruled over semi-feudalistic
villages, factory workers received very low wages and there was an absence of
rights. On the other hand, the American Occupation army removed in one breath
the dictatorial emperor system, unleashing a flowering movement from below which
they then had to suppress and force back into the framework of a bourgeois
state. Thus, because the Meiji Restoration was a ‘bureaucratic semi-bourgeois
revolution from above’ which prevented a bourgeois revolution from below, the
postwar reforms carried out by the American Occupation army were a
‘supplementary bourgeois revolution from above’ to prevent a socialist
revolution from below. Thus Japan set a rare precedent against Trotsky’s
prognosis that backward capitalist countries, in order to join the group of
advanced capitalist countries, would have to go through the experience of
permanent revolution.”
— Nishijima Sakae, Torotsukii Kenkyu (Trotsky Studies),
Summer 2001 (our translation)
The Trotsky Research Institute was formed in 1990 primarily by
members of the Japan Revolutionary Communist League (JRCL), part of the
international pseudo-Trotskyist tendency led at the time by Ernest Mandel. The
Mandelites drew into their misnamed anti-Trotskyist endeavor some JCP
intellectuals, like Nishijima Sakae, who wrote the article quoted above.
There was no avowedly Trotskyist group in Japan during Trotsky’s
lifetime. It was only under the impact of the 1956 Hungarian political
revolution that disparate elements from the JCP and independent Marxist
intellectuals leaning toward Trotskyism came together to form the heterogeneous
JRCL in 1957. Emerging in the context of the virulent anti-Sovietism of 1950s
Japan, with no historical link to Trotsky’s International Left Opposition, the
Japanese “Trotskyists” rejected Trotsky’s analysis of the bureaucracy as a
contradictory caste and refused to militarily defend the USSR. Thus, they were
fundamentally crippled from the beginning. Misidentifying Trotskyism as a simple
democratic opposition to Stalinism, the JRCL and their JCP allies in the TRI
joined the virulently anti-Soviet Japanese bourgeoisie in hailing the
destruction of the Soviet Union and the deformed workers states of East
Europe.
Before considering what actually happened in Japan under the U.S.
Occupation regime of General MacArthur, it is first necessary to address a
common confusion at the theoretical level. Liberals and social democrats often
assign the label “bourgeois-democratic revolution” or simply “democratic
revolution” to any political upheaval which results in a change to a
parliamentary system, whether effected by external forces or internally. But the
concept of a bourgeois revolution in an advanced capitalist country is a
contradiction in terms. Thus the uprising led by the Social Democrats in Germany
in November 1918 which overthrew Kaiser Wilhelm II, in the wake of Germany’s
defeat in the First World War, was not a bourgeois-democratic
revolution. It was an incipient proletarian revolution. The
working class not only demanded the overthrow of the Kaiser, but created workers
and soldiers councils—soviets—all over the country. However, the Social
Democratic leadership in bloc with the army high command and right-wing
paramilitary forces bloodily suppressed the organs of proletarian dual power and
exterminated the revolutionary vanguard of the German working class represented
by Rosa Luxemburg and Karl Liebknecht. In the aftermath, a parliamentary
government (the Weimar Republic) was established, which lasted until it was
replaced by the Nazi regime of Adolf Hitler in 1933. The successive governments
of Kaiser Wilhelm II, the Social Democratic leader Friedrich Ebert and the
fascist Adolf Hitler all politically represented the German
financial and industrial bourgeoisie personified by Siemens and Krupp.
In Italy and western Germany as well as Japan, the post-1945
American-led military occupation brought about parliamentary governments. Unlike
the Japanese emperor system, the bourgeois character of the Italian and German
fascist regimes was manifest, certainly to Marxists, even though Italy retained
the monarchy. Mussolini and Hitler originally came to power under conditions of
fragile parliamentarist regimes shaken by massive social turbulence. Decisive
sections of the Italian and German bourgeoisies supported the fascist movement
out of fear of “red revolution.” Thus leading German capitalist magnate Alfred
Hugenberg, a former director of the Krupp empire, played a key role in
installing Hitler as chancellor.
The emperor system of Hirohito was obviously of a different
political character than the fascist regimes of Mussolini and Hitler. Not only
was it derived from the feudal epoch, but Japan had never experienced
parliamentary democracy. Nonetheless, the government of Hirohito and General
Tojo politically represented the dominant sections of Japanese financial and
industrial capital.
Neither the economic dominance nor the composition of the upper
echelon of the Japanese bourgeoisie changed under the American Occupation. U.S.
authorities initially talked about breaking up the zaibatsu, as part of a
plan to wreck any possibility of Japan’s re-emergence as an industrial power. In
the end nothing was actually done in this regard. The conventional
identification today of Japanese capitalism with the names Mitsubishi, Mitsui,
Sumitomo et al. testifies to the continuity of the Japanese ruling
class from the Meiji era through the present.
The U.S. Occupation regime also preserved the continuity of the
Japanese civilian (as distinct from military) political elite. Hirohito remained
emperor, although forced to publicly abjure the claim of divine lineage. Yoshida
Shigeru, the prime minister during most of the Occupation and also the first
post-Occupation years, had been a senior diplomat in pre-1945 imperial Japan,
serving among other posts as ambassador to Britain. The other top Japanese
officials under the Occupation had career résumés similar to, if less exalted
than, Yoshida’s.
Below the level of the top government officials, the civilian state
bureaucracy, including its extensive police apparatus, was preserved intact and
served as the administrative agency which implemented the policies of
MacArthur’s General Headquarters (GHQ). Even members of the notorious Tokko
(Special Security Police), commonly known as the thought-control police, were
simply reassigned to other ministries. No doubt, many of them were instrumental
in carrying out the “red purge” undertaken by the U.S. authorities in the later
years of the Occupation.
In Italy and western Germany, the changes effected during the
American-led occupation were mainly limited to the political superstructure.
There were no substantial changes at the economic base of these societies. In
Japan, however, the U.S. Occupation regime carried out a land reform that
transformed the mass of tenant farmers into small and middling agrarian
proprietors. Announcing this reform in late 1945, MacArthur, a right-wing
American militarist, declared it would “destroy the economic bondage which has
enslaved the Japanese farmer for centuries of feudal oppression” (quoted in R.P.
Dore, Land Reform in Japan [London: Oxford University Press, 1959]).
As we have seen, the main body of Japanese leftists, represented by
the JCP, had long maintained that feudal forms of exploitation continued to
predominate in agriculture. To assess the specific import of MacArthur’s land
reform, it is necessary to consider the overall policies of the American
Occupation regime, especially as they interacted with the escalating Cold War in
East Asia marked by the 1949 Chinese Revolution and the Korean War of
1950-53.
The Labor Upsurge and the U.S. Occupation
The Occupation can be divided into three phases. The first,
“liberal” phase saw a massive upsurge of working-class radicalism. This was
followed by a period, dubbed the “reverse course” by historians, of political
reaction and repression combined with economic austerity. The final period,
precipitated by the outbreak of the Korean War in June 1950, marked the
formation of the alliance between American imperialism and reviving Japanese
imperialism against the Soviet Union and China.
The labor upsurge was sparked in September 1945 by a strike of
Chinese prisoners of war and Korean forced laborers in the mines of Hokkaido.
The Japanese government and mine owners hired thugs to instigate racist attacks,
but their attempts to turn Japanese workers against their Chinese and Korean
class brothers met with defeat. The courageous actions of the Hokkaido miners
sparked a wider strike wave. By December 1946, 92 percent of the miners in Japan
were organized. A year and a half after the war’s end, nearly 4.5 million
workers were enrolled in trade unions, compared to fewer than a half million at
the prewar peak.
The Communist Party was the only major political organization in
imperial Japan that had opposed the imperialist drive toward colonization and
world war. Consequently, its leaders and cadres emerged from prison or returned
from exile with enormous moral authority extending well beyond the party’s
previous base of support. One American liberal historian recounts in his major
study of the Occupation:
“That the most principled resistance to the war had come from
dedicated Communists gave these individuals considerable status. When Tokuda
Kyuichi and several hundred other Communists were released from prison, they
became celebrities and instant heroes in a society whose old heroes had all
suddenly been toppled. Similarly, [JCP leader] Nosaka Sanzo’s arrival in January
1946 after a long journey from China attracted a great crowd. He, too, received
a hero’s welcome; even conservatives, it was said, joined in.”
— John Dower, Embracing Defeat, Japan in the Wake of World War
II (New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1999)
The public meetings which greeted the release of the JCP leaders
attracted large numbers of ethnic Koreans. Korean JCP leader Kim Ch’on-hae
played a central role in organizing the militant Korean organization Chouren; he
toured the country urging Koreans to join Chouren and the JCP. JCP militants won
leadership of the most militant union federation, Sanbetsu. The working class
was clearly on the offensive. The most dramatic and significant aspect of labor
radicalism in this period was the formation of “production control” committees
which took over factories and challenged the traditional authority of management
and ownership. An American left-liberal publicist who visited Japan at the time
wrote:
“In the early days of the occupation most disputes were settled
quickly, and usually with a victory for the union. Employers were stunned by the
defeat, disorganized and uncertain, fearful of antagonizing the occupation
forces, and in some cases, no doubt, apprehensive of revolutionary
developments.”
— Miriam S. Farley, Aspects of Japan’s Labor Problems (New
York: The John Day Company, 1950)
Land Reform and the Defeat of the Postwar Upsurge
The land reform program implemented by MacArthur was explicitly
designed to prevent the rural masses from joining forces with the urban
working-class upsurge. On May Day 1946 three million workers and peasants
participated in nationwide demonstrations. With a growing food crisis, Citizens
Food Control Committees were springing up in various parts of the country. On
May 19, a Food May Day was held in Tokyo with 300,000 workers and poor farmers
surrounding the prime minister’s office and demanding his resignation.
These events frightened the Occupation forces, and in response they
hurried to bring out a land reform program, which was finally announced in
October 1946. A third of all arable land in Japan (just short of two million
cho—almost five million acres) was transferred from landlords to tenant farmers.
Landlords were required to sell this land to the government, which in turn
resold it at the same purchase price to their tenants or other working farmers.
The financial side of this operation was greatly facilitated by the high rate of
inflation at the time. Both the government and the farmers who purchased land
from it were able to pay in rapidly depreciating yen. Most tenants did not need
recourse to long-term loans but were able to buy the land outright for cash in a
year or two.
The proportion of land cultivated under some form of tenancy
arrangement declined from 45 to 10 percent. And the number of purely tenant
farmers (i.e., those who did not own any land) declined from 28 to 5 percent of
all farmers. There was thus a substantial change in the structure of land
ownership and a reduction in the surplus value (rent and interest) extracted
from the rural toilers. This defused unrest in the countryside and allowed
MacArthur to concentrate on defeating the working class in the cities.
Meanwhile, in the cities labor and the Japanese government were
headed toward a major confrontation. The economic situation continued to
disintegrate, with prices of basic necessities increasing nearly four-fold.
Discontent was also fed by the sense that nothing much had changed in the
political structure of the country. Sanbetsu called for a general strike on 1
February 1947, demanding not only higher wages but the ouster of the right-wing,
widely despised Yoshida government, and for the establishment of a “people’s
government,” demands that were enthusiastically supported by all three major
union federations representing some four million workers. But the Japanese
Stalinists, like their counterparts in West Europe, were unwilling and
unprepared to fight for political power. Frightened, but desiring to save face,
they asked MacArthur’s headquarters to issue a written order forbidding the
strike, which MacArthur did. At literally the eleventh hour, Ii Yashiro, head of
the strike committee, called off the strike in a radio announcement.
The JCP handed the working class a huge defeat, negatively shaping
the post-WWII social order. They also lost an enormous opportunity to cut
through the virulent Japanese nationalism which had tied the working class to
its rulers. Chouren had collected money and organized strike support committees,
writing in its newspaper, “The February general strike planned by the Japanese
working class, which is in our mutual interest, should be our struggle. Their
victory will be our victory and their defeat will be our defeat.” Chouren wasn’t
even informed that the strike was called off! The Stalinists soon lost their
positions of strength and authority throughout the country.
The U.S. Occupation regime now moved to break the leftist-led labor
movement. In 1948, MacArthur’s headquarters banned all strikes by government
workers, who had heretofore been in the forefront of labor militancy. This was
followed by a major “red purge.” Some 20,000 Communist Party activists and other
leftists were fired from their jobs. As a result, the membership of Sanbetsu
plummeted from over a million in mid 1949 to less than 300,000 a year later. The
social democratic-led unions, too, lost members in this period.
Japan emerged from the Occupation with the weakest
labor movement of any major advanced capitalist country. In 1953 a strike at
Nissan was defeated. In the aftermath, the private industrial sector workers
were organized into company-financed and -controlled “unions.” In this way it
was the repressive policies of the “reverse course,” not the “progressive”
reforms of the earlier period, which contributed greatly to the Japanese
“economic miracle” of the 1950s-’60s.
Agriculture, the Cold War and the Japanese “Economic Miracle”
The claim that the land reform implemented under the American
Occupation constituted some kind of bourgeois revolution is most often based on
the argument that the pre-1945 agrarian system blocked Japan’s further
modernization. This argument has two components. The first is the belief that
the impoverished condition of the rural toilers limited the domestic market for
industrial products. The second is that the development of a modern agriculture
sector was essential to Japan’s development and that the poverty of the pre-WWII
tenant farmers blocked this development since they lacked both the financial
means and economic incentives to invest in modern technology.
In the historical short term, the increase in disposable income
among farm households as a result of the land reform was spent, predictably,
almost entirely on consumption rather than investment. To a large extent the
increased consumption of former tenant farmers and their families simply
replaced that of their former landlords. In any case, the increased consumer
demand for manufactured goods in the rural villages was at most a minor
contributing factor to Japan’s rapid industrial growth in the 1950s.
The second component of the argument also does not withstand
scrutiny. The leaders of Meiji Japan pursued a policy of agricultural
self-sufficiency for the same reason they effectively barred foreign investment
and built up a modern military-industrial complex: to protect Japan’s
independence against the threat of Western imperialist states. In the 1890s, the
leading Meiji statesman, Tani Kanjo, a onetime minister of agriculture and
commerce, declared that Japan had to be able to feed itself in the event of war,
that self-sufficiency in basic foodstuffs was even more important than
self-sufficiency in modern weaponry.
However, it was inefficient and contrary to the dynamics of the
world capitalist market for Japan to retain a significant agricultural sector.
Thus a major economic motive for Japan’s colonialist expansionism into East
Asia, from the 1890s through the 1930s, was to obtain secure sources of
relatively cheap, basic foodstuffs as well as raw materials for industry. When
in late 1941 Japan went to war with the U.S., 31 percent of its rice and 58
percent of its soybeans came from Manchuria and the other occupied regions of
China, in addition to Japan’s older Asian colonies of Korea and Formosa
(Taiwan).
The most significant effect of the land reform sponsored by the
American Occupation authorities was at the political, rather than economic
level. In the 1920s and early 1930s, tenant farmers and other peasant
smallholders had engaged in mass, organized struggle under the leadership of
Communists and other leftists against the rapacious landlords and village
moneylenders. When in the mid to late 1940s Japanese peasants acquired their own
land along with government-subsidized loans, they became politically
conservative. Rural villages provided a large (though gradually diminishing)
fraction of the votes which have kept the right-wing Liberal Democratic Party
(LDP) in governmental power in Tokyo for all but a brief period in the mid
1990s. The LDP continues to retain a farming sector for political reasons. This
entails not only a high level of protectionism, but also massive economic
subsidies and rural public works programs which are a drain on the overall
economy.
The “red purge” and union-busting offensive initiated in 1947 by
the U.S. Occupation regime initially coincided with and were reinforced by a
program of economic austerity. This was known as the “Dodge line” after its main
architect, a right-wing Detroit banker, Joseph Dodge. Under Dodge’s orders, the
Japanese government slashed expenditures while the supply of money and credit
was sharply contracted. As a consequence 500,000 workers were laid off in both
the government and private sectors. An estimated third of all small businesses
went bankrupt.
Yet two decades later it had become commonplace to speak of a
Japanese “economic miracle.” The root cause of Japan’s dramatic change of
economic fortunes lay in world-historic events on the Asian mainland. When in
1945 the U.S. defeated Japan, the American imperialists believed they had
finally gained control of China, the great prize for which the Pacific War was
mainly fought. U.S. ruling circles looked to Chiang Kai-shek’s regime in Beijing
as their main point of support in East Asia. This was indicated at the
diplomatic level by making China one of five permanent members of the Security
Council of the newly formed United Nations. In line with Washington’s
China-oriented strategy, Japan was to be kept down, prevented from again
becoming a major (and potentially rival) capitalist power in the Far East.
When, however, in 1949 Mao Zedong’s peasant-based People’s
Liberation Army routed Chiang’s forces in the Chinese civil war, American
imperialism’s plans for domination of East Asia were thrown into disarray. The
U.S. rulers moved to build up Japan as their main strategic ally in the region,
a move greatly accelerated by the Korean War. It was this major war between
American imperialism and the Asian Communist countries which finally pulled
Japan out of its prolonged post-1945 economic depression.
Mitsubishi, Toyota et al., became quartermasters for the American
expeditionary forces in Korea, supplying them with a wide array of matériel,
from trucks and ammunition to uniforms and pharmaceuticals. During the first
eight months of the war, steel production increased by almost 40 percent.
Japanese industry was also mobilized to provide repair facilities for U.S. naval
vessels, aircraft and tanks. Prime Minister Yoshida exultantly described the
Korean War as “a gift of the gods.”
Thus began the Japanese “economic miracle” that would last another
two decades. During the 1950s-’60s, Japan consistently ran large balance of
trade surpluses with the U.S. The powers that be on Wall Street and in
Washington accepted this at the time as part of the overhead costs of
maintaining their strategic alliance with Japan against the Sino-Soviet states.
Not until the early 1970s did the U.S. move to stem the flood of Japanese
manufactured imports through various protectionist devices. This marked the
beginning of the end of the Japanese “economic miracle.” In the decade since the
counterrevolutionary destruction of the Soviet Union, Japan has been mired in a
prolonged economic slump.
Forward to a Japanese Workers Republic!
When the JCP—under pressure from Moscow—finally began to oppose the
Occupation, it contended that the Allied troops had turned Japan into a
dependency, even a “semicolony,” of American imperialism. In 1950, JCP Secretary
General Tokuda Kyuichi compared Japan to pre-1949 China under the American
puppet regime of Chiang Kai-shek! Under the pretext that an “anti-imperialist”
revolution is necessary to rid Japan of its dependent status, to this day the
JCP continues to promote the two-stage schema:
“The present state of Japan is marked by its state subordination
to the United States, which is extraordinary not only among the developed
capitalist countries but in international relations of the present-day world, in
which colonization is history. The U.S. domination of Japan clearly has an
imperialistic character because it tramples on Japan’s sovereignty and
independence in the interests of U.S. global strategy and U.S. monopoly
capitalism....
“A change Japanese society needs at present is a democratic
revolution instead of a socialist revolution. It is a revolution that ends
Japan’s extraordinary subordination to the United States and the tyrannical rule
by large corporation and business circles, a revolution that secures Japan’s
genuine independence and carries out democratic changes in politics, the economy
and society.”
— Nihon Kyosan-to Koryo (Japanese Communist Party Program),
adopted at 23rd Congress, January 2004 (JCP draft translation)
A 1956 article in the Rebel, a direct precursor to the
pseudo-Trotskyist JRCL, described Japan in language similar to the Stalinists as
“a special dependency which lies between a colony and a dependency.” This is a
view which pervades the reformist Japanese left. Thus the “New Left” group
Kakumaru, which originated as a virulently Stalinophobic split from the JRCL in
1958, fulminates that:
“The Koizumi regime accepts all political, economic and military
requests demanded by the Bush regime.... While Koizumi may wear a headband with
a hinomaru [rising sun] on it, his underpants are oversized stars and stripes
trunks and his shoes are U.S. military boots.”
—Kaiho (Liberation), 19 January 2004 (our translation)
With its overwhelming military superiority, the U.S. remains the
predominant imperialist power on the face of the planet. But in the face of
growing tensions with the U.S., particularly since the counterrevolutionary
collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991-92, the Japanese bourgeoisie has
dramatically increased its efforts to build up its military to match its
economic power and to demonstrate its determination to protect its own
imperialist interests throughout Asia. Japan dispatched naval vessels, aircraft
and 1,000 military personnel to the Indian Ocean to aid the U.S. invasion of
Afghanistan in 2001. It has a contingent of approximately 500 soldiers
participating in the occupation of Iraq. In portraying Japan as being under the
thumb of American imperialism, the pseudo-socialist left shows itself to be
mired in Japanese nationalism, playing into the hands of the most extreme
revanchist elements of the Japanese bourgeoisie.
At the First Congress of the Toilers of the Far East in
January-February 1922 Zinoviev correctly declared, “The Japanese proletariat
holds in their hands the key to the solution of the Far Eastern question.” While
the proletariat now has real social weight in other Asian countries, the
Japanese working class remains the powerhouse of the region. If Japanese workers
are not to be plunged into mass unemployment or new imperialist adventures, they
must join with the workers of Indonesia, Vietnam, Thailand, China and the Korean
peninsula in the fight for a socialist Asia. In particular, this means rallying
to the military defense of the states where capitalism has been abolished in
Asia—China, North Korea and Vietnam—despite their Stalinist leaderships. A
proletarian revolution in Japan would be a powerful impetus to the Chinese
proletariat to throw out the bureaucrats who are opening the country up to
imperialist exploitation and the threat of internal counterrevolution. But this
means breaking with the virulent nationalism that is the ideological
justification for Japanese imperialism.
In his 1933 article, Trotsky noted that “The hasty mixture of
Edison with Confucius has left its mark on all of Japanese culture.” Japan today
continues to be marked in myriad ways by the feudal past. Article 1 of the
postwar constitution declares that the emperor is “the symbol of the State and
of the unity of the people” and he continues to serve as a powerful rallying
point for all the reactionary forces in Japanese society. All official dates,
both government and commercial, are figured in terms of the year of the current
emperor’s reign. The state continues to base itself on Shinto mythology, with
its racist notion of the superiority of the Yamato peoples. Japanese citizenship
is not automatically granted even to fourth- and fifth-generation Korean and
Chinese born in Japan.
There continues to be discrimination against those whose ancestry
is Burakumin. Because the majority of Burakumin are forced to live in segregated
neighborhoods, the address on the state’s familial registration papers
immediately identifies them. Burakumin children are bullied at school, adults
are denied jobs, and in many cases lovers are separated by reactionary relatives
who still believe the Burakumin are subhuman.
Japan—home to the bullet train, Sony PlayStation, robotics and
developer of state of the art precision technology—has the technological
capability, if placed in the hands of the world’s working class, to tremendously
accelerate the elimination of hunger, want and disease. But women are still
prohibited from entering tunnels under construction for bullet trains out of
fear that the “mountain goddess” will become jealous. Nor can they step inside a
sumo dojo (wrestling ring), because they are “impure.” The Japanese
language continues to have a demeaning four-tiered structure requiring different
levels of submissiveness depending on the class, age, sex and social status of
the person one is addressing. Onna kotoba, a separate spoken language for
women, deliberately promotes obedience and submissiveness and is required for
all public functions and for use inside the family when a woman addresses her
in-laws. The SGJ fights for the elimination of status, age and sex
discrimination, and their concomitant reflection in demeaning language.
In almost all social indices Japanese women place at the bottom of
the advanced industrial countries. Just over half of Japanese women work,
compared with 70 percent of their Western counterparts. The “good wife, wise
mother” ideology is codified in law and corporate practices. Most companies
provide male workers with family allowances if the wife does not work; these
allowances are often more than a married woman working part-time could make.
Seventy-seven percent of all part-time workers in Japan are female. On average,
women’s salaries are just 60 percent of men’s, and this percentage has remained
steady since women first entered the workforce as textile workers in the late
1800s. The social pressure exerted on a woman who hits 30 to marry and assume
her “appropriate place” in society is immense. Older unmarried women are
referred to as makeinu (losing dogs) and motenai onna (unwanted
females).
The International Communist League stands on the heritage of
Trotsky’s Fourth International, studying with a critical eye its programmatic
and political decisions in order to arm ourselves for future battles. Similarly,
a critical approach to our legacy from the first four congresses of the
Communist International has led us to have left reservations about some of the
decisions made at and around the Fourth Congress. The Spartacist Group Japan
continues the fight to forge an authentically communist party in Japan. This
party can only be built on the basis of uncompromising struggle against
recrudescent Japanese chauvinism, resurgent militarism, and the horrible
oppression of women. The Sasebo dock workers who refused to load military goods
onto Japanese military ships bound for the Indian Ocean in 2001 provided a
powerful example to the proletariat internationally. Abolish the emperor system!
Japanese troops out of Iraq, the Indian Ocean, East Timor and the Golan Heights!
For an end to the discrimination against the Burakumin and Ainu! Throw the
family registry into the trash bin! For full citizenship for ethnic Koreans and
Chinese and all who live in Japan! Tear up the gaijin (foreigner) cards!
Equal pay for equal work! For free, safe birth control and free, 24-hour
childcare and nursing care for the elderly! The Spartacist Group Japan champions
demands such as these as part of its overall program for socialist revolution.
It is only on this program that the revolutionary proletarian party which can
lead the fight to overthrow capitalism in Japan can be forged. Forward to a
Japanese workers republic!
Endnote
A selection of documents from the Comintern archives on the JCP has
been published in Russian in VKP(b), Komintern i Yaponiya 1917-1941
(The VKP(b) [All-Union Communist Party (bolshevik)], the Comintern and Japan,
1917-1941 [Moscow: Russian Political Encyclopedia, 2001]), which we
consulted for this article. In 1998 and 1999, Professor Kato Tetsuro, a
social-democratic, anti-Communist historian, published the results of his
research into the JCP Comintern archives in Japanese in a series of articles,
“1922.9 no Nihon Kyosan-to Koryo” [ue, shita]; “Dai Ichi-ji Kyosan-to no
Mosukuwa Hokoku Sho” [ue, shita] (Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyujo Zasshi,
Hosei Daigaku, Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyujo, 1998.12, 1999.1, 1999.8, 1999.11)
(“1922 Program of the Japanese Communist Party” [Parts I and II] and “Moscow
Report of the First Communist Party” [Parts I and II], Ohara Institute for
Social Research Journal, December 1998, January, August, November 1999). The
comprehensive collection of microfilmed documents, Comintern Archives: Files
of the Communist Party of Japan, published in the spring of 2004 by IDC
publishers in the Netherlands, was unfortunately not yet available for the
preparation of this article.
Manifesto
by the Preparatory Committee for the Japanese Communist Party
April 1921
by the Preparatory Committee for the Japanese Communist Party
April 1921
This document was written in English by Yamakawa Hitoshi and
sent to representatives of the Communist International in Shanghai for
transmission to Moscow. Unfortunately, the original English version could not be
located in the Comintern Archives in the Russian State Archive of
Socio-Political History in Moscow. We translated this from the Russian
version—first published in The Peoples of the Far East (No. 4, 1921)—as
it appears in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan. The process of
retranslation, while unavoidable, has no doubt introduced drift and perhaps
inaccuracies.
At the time this manifesto was written, the Soviet Red Army was
conducting mopping-up operations in the wake of its victory over imperialist
interventionist forces and the counterrevolutionary White armies operating under
their patronage. Anton Deniken, Peter Wrangel, Alexander Kolchak and G.
Semenov—all former tsarist officers—were military commanders of the White
forces. Alexander Kerensky was head of the bourgeois Provisional Government that
had been overthrown by the Bolsheviks in October 1917. In the summer of 1918
Japanese imperialist forces invaded the Russian Far East, where they worked in
league with Semenov; Japanese troops did not leave Vladivostok until November
1922.
Seiyukai (Association of Political Friends) was the dominant
bourgeois party in Japan at the time. It was founded in 1900 after the
decomposition of Jiyuto (Liberal Party), and evolved into a diehard conservative
party. In 1900, Hara Takashi (also known as Hara Kei) joined Seiyukai and became
its secretary general, running the party with several others through 1914. The
so-called “People’s Cabinet” (Heimin Naikaku) refers to the cabinet in which
Hara was prime minister, formed after the 1918 Rice Riots. Because Hara was
neither a member of the peerage nor from any of the four domains (i.e., Satsuma,
Choshu, Tosa or Hizen) that had dominated the government from 1868, he has been
called the “commoner” prime minister. Hara’s popularity declined due to his
relentless opposition to universal suffrage and he was assassinated in November
1921.
A spectre is haunting Europe, said Karl Marx at one time. Today,
after 75 years, this spectre is haunting not only Europe, but the whole world.
The powers of the whole world have united in one holy alliance to drive away the
spectre of communism. The League of Nations, the League of Denikins, Wrangels
and Kerenskys with French and British imperialists; the union of Kolchaks with
Semenovs and Japanese militarists, just as thousands of other leagues and
alliances, all bear witness to the fact that capitalism is placing its final
decisive stake in its struggle for its existence.
The Revolution of 1867 was the victory of mercantile capital over
feudalism. Capitalist relations had not sufficiently matured up to that point in
time, however, and could not, for this reason, also correspondingly reconstruct
the political system. Power went to the lower layers of the old privileged
classes, instead of passing directly to the bourgeoisie. This circumstance
became the reason for the rise of a most complex bureaucratic apparatus and
despotic monarchy in Japan—instead of bourgeois republicanism.
Industrial capitalism continued to develop from this point on in
Japan under the paternal wing of the bureaucracy. The bureaucracy from its own
side clearly took into account the fact that it could not survive without
collaboration with the capitalists. Thus the past 50 years (from the moment of
the 1867 Revolution) is the history of the development of capitalism under the
sluggish and clumsy bureaucracy.
The Sino-Japanese and Russo-Japanese wars were decisive for the
history of capitalism in Japan. We all remember how Japanese capitalism bloated,
gorging on the suffering and blood of not only its own people, but of the
proletariat of neighboring countries. On this basis militarism and imperialism
with such determination sank deep roots into the sun-drenched islands of the Far
East.
The four years of the great European war afforded enough time and
opportunity for Japanese capitalism to enter the world arena fully armed.
The development of capitalism prior to its present state naturally
found its reflection in the political situation of the country, as the so-called
“People’s Cabinet” (Heimin Naikaku)—a government composed exclusively of
representatives of the parties of large landlords and capitalists,
“Seiyukai”—reached a dominant position, monopolizing parliament, the
municipalities, stock market and banks. The hour had finally arrived, when the
bourgeoisie of Japan could come out independently, no longer hiding behind or
seeking the protection of the monarchical bureaucracy. From this moment of the
bourgeoisie’s open entry into the arena, the proletariat of Japan understood
what its own position was in society.
In this way, the progress of capitalism in Japan, true as ever to
its historic mission, gave impetus to the proletarian movement. The sharp growth
of the workers movement in 1918 and later on, the innumerable strikes and
workers protests, the rapid awakening and development of class consciousness of
the workers, the powerful, unstoppable spread of socialist doctrine throughout
the country—all of this is the fruit of the economic development of Japan.
This development is typical not only for the cities and suburbs.
The rural population has been drawn in as well. The rapid capitalization of
land, the swallowing of small farms by large landlords have had the result of
placing 60 percent of the population in the ranks of the proletariat. And today
there is no doubt that a significant majority of the rural population will
consciously go shoulder to shoulder with the urban proletariat in the coming
battle for liberation. The decisive class differentiation between the
proletariat and bourgeoisie in Japan—this is an already accomplished fact, and
both classes are carrying on an intense struggle with each other. The “Rice
Riots” that swept the country in the summer of 1918 and that within two weeks
made the government tremble in their boots fired the revolutionary spirit of the
broad masses. This was an indication that the moment of decisive struggle for
the overthrow of capitalism has arrived.
Alongside the proletarian movement, the influence of socialism has
grown in Japan as well. For an entire quarter of a century Japanese socialists
courageously, but unsuccessfully fought with those mighty forces that were
organized by the gigantic police apparatus of the militarist bureaucracy. But
the time has finally arrived when we may reward ourselves for all the past
sacrifices. We now have a truly revolutionary proletariat; the broad popular
masses are seized by a spirit of indignation; we have in addition the Communist
Party of Japan, the vanguard of the proletarian revolutionary army.
Further, at the same time as capitalist Japan has entered the arena
of international capitalist exploitation, the Japanese proletariat has entered
onto the broad road of World Revolution. When the proletariat of Russia
overthrew its oppressors in the momentous October days, the left wing of
Japanese socialists, in spite of vigilance of the police and spy networks,
joyfully hailed the brilliant victory of their Russian comrades. We stated then,
“The proletariat of each country must eliminate the bayonets aimed against the
workers of other countries, and aim them against their genuine enemies in their
own countries.”
We were too weak then to carry out our words in deeds, but we still
firmly held the banner of international solidarity of the proletariat even in
the period of vicious incessant attacks by the rabid capitalist government. Now
we are able to greet the revolutionary proletariat of all countries in the name
of the Communist Party of Japan.
Long Live the Proletarian Revolution!
Long Live the Communist International!
Long Live Communism!
Program of the Communist Party of Japan
September 1922
September 1922
This program was written in English in September 1922 and sent
to Moscow for the Fourth Congress of the Communist International, which was held
in November-December 1922. We publish here the original English version found in
the Archives of the Communist International in the Russian State Archive of
Socio-Political History in Moscow. We have added obvious dropped words,
corrected obvious misspellings and use of definite articles and prepositions,
but otherwise not changed the somewhat awkward English.
The document was sent to the Comintern over the signatures of
Aoki Kunekichi (pseudonym of Arahata Kanson), as General Secretary of the JCP,
and Sakatani Goro (pseudonym of Sakai Toshihiko), as the party’s International
Secretary. They wrote that the program was approved by a national convention of
the JCP held in September 1922, but we have found no other record that a JCP
conference was held at that time.
The last section of the program opposes Japanese imperialist
expansion in Asia. When the program was written, Japan still maintained troops
in the Russian Far East, which it had invaded during the Russian Civil War.
Japan had fought a war against China in 1894-95, winning Formosa (Taiwan) and
economic control of Korea. In 1904-05, Japan fought tsarist Russia, seizing
strategic Port Arthur in southern Manchuria and Southern Sakhalin Island. In
November 1905 Japan declared Korea its protectorate, and in August 1910 annexed
it outright.
The Communist Party of Japan, a section of the Third Communist
International, is an illegal, proletarian political party, whose aim is the
overthrow of the Capitalist regime through the establishment of the Dictatorship
of the Proletariat based on the Soviet Power.
Japan has been the most powerful of the capitalist nations of the
Orient, and the favourable position she occupied during the World War has
brought about a sudden development and expansion of her capitalistic system.
Under the pressure of the world economic crisis, Japanese Capitalism is
struggling hard to tighten its grip of already unequalled exploitation and
persecution upon the toiling masses, the workers, peasants, and other lower
strata of the population. The Communist Party takes upon itself the task of
organizing these proletarian masses into a powerful fighting body, leading them
on to the Proletarian Revolution—the seizure of political power and system of
production in the hands of the proletariat.
Labour Movement
The workers’ movement in Japan is still in an infantile stage. The
trade union movement, under the yoke of the Japanese Tsardom, has not yet
followed the normal line of development. Side by side with a large number of
passive, intimidated, unorganized masses stands a minority of self-conscious,
militant elements, whose temper and ideology are as revolutionary as those of
the most advanced section of the European workers. Even among the unorganized,
the feeling of instinctive revolt is as wide-spread and deep-rooted as among any
brutally oppressed toilers. To these instinctive revolt and revolutionary
demands the Communist Party strives to give a most clearly defined aim as well
as the most effective methods of realizing it. For this purpose, the Communists
must penetrate into every workers’ organization so as to take control of the
union policies, maintain the closest contact with the unorganized masses so as
to educate, guide and organize them for the proletarian struggle. In this
difficult work, the Party, while holding fast the ultimate aim of establishing
the proletarian dictatorship, must organize its legal activities with the view
to an active participation in the daily struggles of the workers, pushing
through at every opportunity the Communist tactics of the “United Front.” Only
through its successful struggle along these lines can the Communist Party expect
to acquire the character of a proletarian mass party, the true vanguard of the
Proletariat.
Some of the more active, influential sections of the industrial
workers have been infected with the infantile malady of the anarcho-syndicalist
ideology. Naively cherishing an illusory idea of the “Free Workers’ Regime,”
they are opposed to centralized organization and all “political” actions
including the establishment of the Dictatorship of the Proletariat, and are
still in a position to lead and influence a minority of workers, to the
detriment of both the immediate need for undivided effort and the ultimate
victory of the proletariat.
These revolutionary elements, while deserving no concession on the
matters of our principles, must be approached by the party with utmost patience
and generosity in order to win as many of them as possible over to our aims and
tactics.
Agrarian Problems
In the domain of agriculture the process of pauperization has been
steadily going on, resulting in a remarkable growth of tenancy and concentration
of land. This tendency was accelerated by the sudden development and expansion
of industries. Awakened by the rebellious action of the industrial workers, the
rural toilers have started to organize and to fight their class enemy, and found
their position strengthened by an acute labour shortage caused by the War. Even
after the industrial depression has set in, the tenant farmers carry on their
fight and organization. They demand a reduction of rent with the threat of
quitting the cultivation; thousands of acres of land have been abandoned by the
tenants; and the owners are being compelled to till it themselves with aid of
hired labour and agricultural machinery.
In view of the situation, and particularly of the more fundamental
fact that the small farmers and the tenants occupy nearly seventy per cent of
the entire population, and without their aid the proletarian victory is
impossible, the Communist Party of Japan should take initiative in the
organization of tenants, carry on an untiring agitation and propaganda in the
villages so that the rural workers may come to understand Communist ideas and
see their only salvation in the Social Revolution.
Political Action
The political parties in this country are the parties of the
Capitalist Class. Their rule, however, is checked by the influence of the
Bureaucrats and Militarist Clique, the remnants of Feudal Japan. Thus, the
conflicts and compromises of the two forces constitute the bone of the present
day politics. Bourgeois Democracy has yet to see its palmiest [most flourishing]
day, and universal suffrage has yet to be fought for.
The Communist Party, while convinced fully of the truth that the
Parliamentary System as such is nothing but a bourgeois institution and in no
way dependable as an instrument of proletarian revolution, nevertheless holds
that its perfection constitutes an essential stage in the normal development of
proletarian struggle. The party, therefore, organizes proletarian political
action to help accelerate the “progress of Democracy.” Our political activities
within and without the parliament, however, must remain a feature of our general
Communist propaganda and agitation. They shall consist in broadening and
intensifying the proletarian struggle on the one hand, and in exposing the
hypocrisy and futility of bourgeois democracy, and demonstrating to the
proletariat the necessity of creating their own machinery of Government on the
other hand. Only thus, the Party believes, will the proletariat be convinced of
the essentially political nature of their struggle and become ready to carry
their fight to the finish, the seizure of political power. And only thus, we are
confident, will the proletariat follow the lead of our party whose goal it is to
establish the Proletarian Dictatorship based on the Soviet of the workers,
peasants and soldiers.
Militarism
The Japanese Empire, known as the Germany of the Orient, has its
world-famous Militarist Bureaucracy. The Jingoes of Japan do not shrink from the
idea of a war with the United States. And their natural allies are the bourgeois
capitalists, whose greed for markets is insatiable.
The secret of the militarist influence lies in their patriotism.
The patriotism which they have been so eager to preach in the schools and armies
still has its hold upon a large mass of people. Blinded and deafened by the
poison of patriotism, they are not yet able to realize that the real function of
the army is to maintain capitalist rule, enabling the capitalists to exploit and
oppress the producing masses ever and ever more effectively.
The Communist Party is determined to fight militarism. By breaking
the spell of patriotism, it must upset the foundation of militarist power, and
thus prepare the way to the organization of the Red army of the revolutionary
proletariat.
Korean, Chinese, and Siberian Questions
The Communist Party of Japan is resolutely opposed to every species
of the Imperialist policy. It is opposed to the intervention, open and secret,
in China and Siberia, the interference with the government of these countries,
the “Sphere of Influence” and “Vested Interests” in China, Manchuria, and
Mongolia, and all the other attempts and practices of similar nature.
The most infamous of all the crimes of Japanese Imperialism has
been the annexation of Korea and the enslavement of the Korean people. The
Communist Party of Japan not only condemns the act but takes every available
step for the emancipation of Korea. The majority of the Korean patriots,
fighting for the Independence of Korea, is not free from bourgeois ideology and
nationalist prejudice. It is necessary that we act in cooperation with
them—necessary not only for the victory of the Korean Revolution but also for
winning them over to our Communist principles. The Korean Revolution will bring
with it a national crisis in Japan, and the fate of both the Korean and Japanese
proletariat will depend on the success or failure of the fight carried on by the
united effort of the Communist Parties of the two countries.
The three principal nations in the Far East, China, Korea, and
Japan, are most closely related to one another in their political, social, and
economic life, and thus bound to march together on to the goal of Communism. The
international solidarity of the proletariat, and particularly of these three
countries is the condition indispensable to the Victory and Emancipation of the
Proletariat, not only of the respective countries but of the whole world.
Report on Differences at the Special Congress of the Japanese
Communist Party
by Arahata Kanson
May 1923
by Arahata Kanson
May 1923
This report on the 15 March 1923 JCP Congress was written in
Japanese in Moscow for the Third Plenum of the Executive Committee of the
Communist International, which was held in June 1923. Unfortunately, the
Japanese original could not be located in the Comintern Archives in the Russian
State Archive of Socio-Political History in Moscow. We have translated this from
the Russian version which appeared in The VKP(b), the Comintern and Japan.
This Russian text was translated from an English version which was made from
the original Japanese by the Comintern. The process of translation from Japanese
to English to Russian and back has no doubt introduced drift and perhaps
inaccuracies.
Written using Arahata’s pseudonym of Aoki, this report sought to
amplify a report that Sakai, as International Secretary of the JCP, had sent to
the Comintern in March 1923. Sakai’s report detailed the differences that
developed in the JCP over Bukharin’s 1922 draft JCP program and the “two stage”
conception of revolution it propounded. The language in Sakai’s report, written
under the name Sakatani Goro, is not as clear as that used by Arahata. In
several places in this document, Arahata explains phrases used in Sakai’s
report, which is also published in Russian in The VKP(b), the Comintern and
Japan.
Arahata refers to a Mercantile Industrial Party led by Japanese
textile manufacturer Muto Sanji. Muto’s short-lived, liberal bourgeois party is
better known as Jitsugyo Doshikai (Businessmen’s Association).
Yuaikai (Friendly Society) was Japan’s first major labor
organization, founded in 1912 by the Christian reformer Suzuki Bunji. Kagawa
Toyohiko was also a Christian reformer and Yuaikai leader. Modeled on British
friendly (mutual aid) societies, Yuaikai advocated collaboration between labor
and capital, and concentrated on organizing craft unions. In 1919 Yuaikai was
reorganized more along the lines of an industrial union federation and renamed
Dai Nihon Rodo Sodomei-Yuaikai (Greater Japan General Federation of
Labor-Friendly Societies). The name was later shortened to Nihon Rodo Sodomei
(Japan General Federation of Labor), or simply Sodomei.
The Kakushin Kurabu (Reform Club) was a small party that
represented the most liberal members of the Diet, having as its base of support
the urban middle class and prosperous farmers. It advocated universal suffrage
and a reduced military. Its ranks were divided over passage of the Peace
Preservation Law of 1925, and the Reform Club was dissolved that same year, with
most members joining the dominant bourgeois party, Seiyukai.
When Arahata’s report was written the Communist International
was engaged in an international campaign against the French occupation of the
Ruhr, which began in January 1923, after Germany defaulted on the reparations
payments it was forced to pay France under the terms of the Versailles
Treaty.
Certain points of the CC Report are insufficiently clear and
require explanation.
The question of organizing a legal labor party brought out
differences at our Congress. One part of the party insisted on an immediate
founding of a legal political party, another part maintains that the moment for
this has not yet arrived. The first tendency maintains that a bourgeois
revolution in Japan is inevitable and believes that a proletarian revolution is
only possible after a bourgeois [revolution].
They point to the movement for the founding of the Shoko-to
(Mercantile Industrial Party), led by Japanese cotton king Muto Sanji, to the
efforts toward a political workers party led by the chairman of the “Yuaikai”
(Japanese Federation of Labor), Suzuki Bunji, and to an analogous tendency in
the “Kakushin Kurabu,” as symptoms of the coming bourgeois revolution.
If there is not an active Communist Party that will take the
leadership of the movement into its hands, the proletariat will fall under the
influence of the bourgeoisie. It is for this reason that they insist on a legal
political workers-peasants party, which must act to hasten the bourgeois
revolution, which sooner or later must come about. This in turn would prepare
the groundwork for the proletarian revolution that will follow after the
bourgeois revolution. This political party must also include radical elements of
the bourgeoisie, since at the present time the proletariat as a whole still
remains under their influence and it would be difficult to ignore them.
The other part of the Congress supports the position that a purely
bourgeois revolution, along the lines of the Great French Revolution or the
March Revolution in Russia, is impossible in Japan as a result of the rapid
development of the Japanese bourgeoisie during the imperialist war, and even
before that.
In its developing stage, the Japanese bourgeoisie leaned on the
bureaucracy, on the remnants of feudalism. But now it is already able to stand
on its own two feet. In addition to which, the bureaucracy has become an
obstacle to the further development of the bourgeoisie.
After the heavy blow that it took from the economic crisis that
followed the war, the bourgeoisie came to the conclusion that the only course
toward re-establishing its forces was the capture of economic and political
power, tearing the latter out of the hands of the bureaucracy.
It is without a doubt that toward the bureaucracy the Japanese
bourgeoisie is quite radical, but as soon as the question touches on the
overthrow of the Mikado and the establishment of a genuine bourgeois democracy
with republican forms of rule, it becomes thoroughly conservative. Thanks to the
living example of Europe, the bourgeoisie understands full well that the
beginning of any revolution will be its death knell. Just as the Mikado, in the
hands of the bureaucracy, had been a tool for the enslavement of the popular
masses, precisely so is the bourgeoisie using him as a tool for the defense of
their interests. The bourgeoisie fully takes into account the attitude of the
Japanese people toward the Mikado. Even though on the one hand the Mikado
represents an obstacle to the bourgeoisie, in other respects he represents a
valuable tool in their hands. In reality, the bourgeoisie only wishes to replace
the present bureaucratic government. But it maintains that this must be done by
completely constitutional means.
It is absolutely clear that, being unable to independently take
power out of the hands of the bureaucracy, the bourgeoisie must enlist the
popular masses to its side. It is exclusively for this reason that Muto has
launched a movement for the aforementioned (Mercantile Industrial Party), whose
central demand is universal suffrage.
For the same reason, Suzuki and the lackeys of the “Kakushin
Kurabu” strive to form a labor party on this same platform of universal
suffrage.
In this context, the basic question is what tactic should be used
against them. We must very carefully monitor every attempt of theirs to win
support from the masses. For the bourgeoisie to corrupt the masses is an
everyday affair in all capitalist states. If we succeed in winning broad support
of the masses and to lead them, then the hour of proletarian revolution has
arrived. We must remain alert, but our vigilance must not lead us to prematurely
form a political party that would include the most heterogeneous elements. This
would be a tactical mistake.
From this standpoint, it follows that the coming revolution in
Japan will be a proletarian revolution, since, as set out above, the bourgeoisie
is extremely conservative on the question of the overthrow of the Mikado. A
revolution like the Great French Revolution, or the March Revolution in Russia
is unthinkable in Japan as long as the masses are not revolutionized; but when
the masses do become revolutionized, then that is when the hour of the
proletarian revolution will strike.
If we help the bourgeoisie in its strivings to seize power, are we
not consolidating the foundations of bourgeois democracy, and are we not thereby
holding back the development of the proletarian revolution? It is without a
doubt so. That is why we must carry out a policy toward proletarian revolution,
and concentrate all of our attention on this goal. (In the Report, the phrase
“striving to the extent we can, to block the political revolution” should be
understood in the sense of “conduct a policy and develop a movement that will
block the consolidation of bourgeois power.”)
It is from this standpoint that there is opposition to the
formation of a political party in which the worker-communists are to form a left
wing, the social democrats the center, and the radical bourgeoisie, the right
wing.
As to the question of founding a purely proletarian political
party, the first part of the Congress maintained that this must be organized
immediately. They believe that the danger of losing the sympathy of radical
(syndicalist) workers by doing this is only a passing danger. The opposition of
syndicalists to a political movement is actually prompted by the propaganda of
revolutionary socialists in the past. Propaganda for a revolutionary political
movement that we propose will without a doubt prove successful among them. On
the other hand, they argue, if we don’t form such a party, the Labor Party that
Suzuki and the lackeys of Kakushin Kurabu are striving to form will attract many
moderate workers.
In counterposition to these views, the second part of the Congress
declared that irrespective of whether we form a political party or not, it is
absolutely inevitable that many workers will be drawn to the envisioned
reformist Labor Party, and will wind up under its influence. This pertains as
well, and even more so, to the peasantry, a large part of which consists, after
all, of peasant landholders.
For instance, on the question of nationalization of land, the
peasantry will support the program of nationalization with
compensation, that is, the program that a radical bourgeois party is
ready to adopt, but that stands in contradiction to the program of
nationalization without compensation, the program put forward by
the proletarian party. At the present moment the rural population is of course
more backward in its political consciousness than the urban workers. In fact, we
face an interesting paradox—the left wing of the urban working class is inclined
against the founding of a political party, believing that such a party would be
limited in its work exclusively to parliamentarism, while the best
and most radical elements of the rural population support a
political movement, proceeding from these very same
assumptions.
The organized and class-conscious part of the peasants who rent and
of rural proletarians represents just as small a portion of their class as the
organized workers represent of theirs. And nonetheless, Suzuki and Kagawa
Toyohiko, the reformist union leaders, who are gradually losing their influence
among urban workers, preserve their influence among rural workers. In general,
the majority of the working masses in the city, as well as in the village, are
moderate, conservative, and even reactionary and for this reason may become
easily ensnared by bourgeois influences.
For this reason our goal must be the winning of not the broad
masses in general, but the winning of the radical, class-conscious part of the
working class. But the radical elements of the working class are at the present
hostile to political activity, while those elements who are not
hostile are the indifferent ones. For example: Suzuki Bunji preaches that the
class struggle can be ameliorated through universal suffrage, and has publicly
declared that if his Labor Party manages to get into parliament the antagonism
between labor and capital will be eased. Yuaikai, of which Suzuki is the
chairman, at its congress last October adopted a resolution
against universal suffrage and declared that if Suzuki joins the
political movement, he will be expelled from the General Confederation of Labor
(Sodomei). That is the situation in the Sodomei, which has more Communist
elements in its ranks than any other labor organization. Of course this
situation was created as a result of an overly narrow interpretation of
political activity. The left wing cannot free itself of its syndicalist
prejudices, and sees all political activity only as parliamentarism.
Nonetheless, those workers who are inclined against a political
movement represent the very best and the most promising elements of the working
class. Isn’t it true that in the majority of cases those who today join in the
political movement are cheap politicians? Aren’t they simply paid agents of the
Kenseikai party, or people bought with money thrown around by the lackeys of the
Kakushin Kurabu? In spite of their traditional disorientation, we must not leave
the best elements of the working class, and we must ourselves see to it that
they do not turn from us. Being the vanguard of the broad masses, they will in
the near future join us under the banner of Communism and will become true
fighters in the front ranks of revolutionary battles. That is why we must teach
them about politics through practical political activity that creates political
discipline on their part, dispel their prejudices against political work, make a
clear and unbroken connection between economic and political questions, and
teach them that in order to attain the economic liberation of the working class,
the proletariat must first of all seize political power.
The Central Executive Committee of the Japanese Communist Party has
resolved to broaden its activity in economic questions. This plan entails the
strengthening of trade unions, the improvement of the workers movement’s
situation, the winning of workers to the party and the reinforcement of the
economic and political sections of the party. Already in the spring of the
previous year the party organized the “Hands Off Soviet Russia!” movement, it
conducted a campaign opposing legislation against thought crimes, it is
campaigning against the occupation of the Ruhr, and is at the present organizing
a movement of the unemployed. Even though these campaigns have had only partial
success, the party has managed to organize a trade-union committee as the
leading body of these movements. In the end, this practical work (in the report
the term that is used is “direct political action”) cannot but help to raise the
class consciousness of the working masses. At first glance this method of work
may seem protracted, but it will lead to great results in the future. Rather, it
is the premature creation of a political party that will risk us our influence
over radical trade unions. These are the important organizations of the
proletariat, who are in principle hostile to the so-called political movement.
In a country like Japan, where the Communist Party is still young and weak, this
represents a very serious danger.
And so, opinions at the Party Congress divided into two: one part
maintains that a bourgeois revolution is inevitable, while the other part does
not. This naturally will lead to differences over tactical questions in the
future. The Congress concluded, leaving these problems unresolved, tabling them
to the party’s sections, departments, and cells for further detailed
discussion.
In essence, there are actually no disagreements over the founding
of a political party; opinions diverge only over whether this party should take
into its ranks only purely proletarian elements, or others as well, and opinions
diverge over whether such a party should be formed immediately, or do we need to
go more slowly with this.
No comments:
Post a Comment